A Really Simple Explanation of Policy Punctuations?
Interdependence, Complexity, and Policy Punctuations
Florian Prange
1
and Søren Serritzlew
2
1
GORDIS GmbH, Bernstorffstraße 118, 22767 Hamburg, Germany
2
University of Aarhus, Bartholins Allé 7, 8000 Aarhus C., Denmark
Keywords: Theory of Budgeting, Policy Punctuations, Agent based Modeling, Complexity, Non-Equilibrium Games.
Abstract: We know for a fact that changes in budgets follow a leptokurtic or power law distribution. We have solid
evidence that the degree of leptokurtosis can be explained by factors such as special features of policy areas,
information processing, decision costs, and differences in the institutional setting (Jones & Baumgartner,
2005a; 2005b, Breunig, 2007; Jones, Sulkin and Larsen, 2003; Breunig and Koski, 2006). However, we do
not know why leptokurtosis is omnipresent. In this paper we conjecture that leptokurtosis can be explained
by four simple observations which must be true of any budgeting process: (1) that several actors request and
spend budgets, (2) several actors allocate funding, (3) that actors which do not receive sufficient funding
will eventually close down, and (4) that available funding is limited and often smaller than requested
funding. We first review the literature on policy punctuations and leptokurtosis, and identify the four simple
observations. We then discuss how a simulation can be useful in investigating the implications of these four
observations, and introduce a simulation of the interaction of beggars and philanthropists in a budget game.
We show that the four observations can account for the omnipresence of leptokurtosis at the sub system
level. They cannot, however, explain the magnitude of leptokurtosis found in empirical distributions of
budget changes.
1 COMPLEX PATTERNS WITH A
SIMPLE EXPLANATION IN
THE THEORY OF POLICY
PUNCTUATION
Public budgeting is, in a sense, very well
understood. When Aaron Wildavsky and his
colleagues almost 50 years ago began to use
quantitative methods in the study of public
budgeting, it became clear that public budgets are,
compared to other phenomena within the realm of
political science, extremely easy to predict. Budgets
almost always develop ‘incrementally’, i.e. they tend
to grow slowly and gradually year after year. If one
knows the budget for one year of a country, a
municipality, a public agency, or some other entity,
it is fairly easy to predict next year’s budget. Just
add a small fraction and you have, almost always, a
very good estimate. This has been documented in
several studies, in various ways and countries (see,
for instance, Davis, Dempster & Wildavsky, 1966;
Jones, Baumgartner & True, 1998).
However, this is only one side of the story.
Although public budgets are indeed predictable and
changes small most of the time, once in a while,
often when least expected, changes of catastrophic
nature occur (Padgett 1980; Jones, Baumgartner &
True, 1998). Figure 1 shows the distribution of
budget changes in U.S. budget outlays for almost
200 years. Compared to a normal distribution, it has
a characteristic form. Small changes are very
frequent, and much more frequent than in a normal
distribution with similar mean and standard
deviation would predict. However, the distribution
has fat tails; extreme changes occur once in a while,
and much more often than would be expected from a
normal distribution. Budget changes follow a
leptokurtic distribution, and the cumulative
frequency of observations is related with a power
function to the size of the change.
This does not only apply to U.S. budget outlays
but is a very strong empirical result. A massive
amount of empirical evidence confirms that budget
97
Prange F. and Serritzlew S..
A Really Simple Explanation of Policy Punctuations? - Interdependence, Complexity, and Policy Punctuations.
DOI: 10.5220/0004055300970102
In Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Simulation and Modeling Methodologies, Technologies and Applications (SIMULTECH-2012),
pages 97-102
ISBN: 978-989-8565-20-4
Copyright
c
2012 SCITEPRESS (Science and Technology Publications, Lda.)
changes follow this distribution, in different
countries, states, municipalities. James True calls
such budget changes avalanches (True 2000).
Figure 1: Real U.S. Budget Outlays, 1800-1994. Note:
Copied from Jones, Sulkin & Larsen (2003: 164).
Sometimes the avalanches are small and affect
only limited parts of the system, sometimes the
avalanches gain momentum and cause dramatic
changes. The tricky part is that it is impossible to
predict when these avalanches occur, both in sand
piles and in budgets. Studies of actual sand piles
have revealed clear patterns of how often it happens,
and of the frequency of avalanches of certain sizes,
but it has proved extremely hard to predict exactly
where and when it occurs (Bak, 1996: 59ff.). The
same is true for public budgets. It is easy to predict
how many avalanches appear within a reasonable
period of time, but the timing usually comes as a
surprise.
This phenomenon calls for an explanation. Two
explanations are available in the literature.
According to the theory of punctuated equilibria
(Baumgartner & Jones, 1993; Jones, Baumgartner &
True, 1998), long periods of stability in political
subsystems, where most decisions are made, will,
once in a while, be broken or punctuated when a
political issue is elevated unto the macro political
level or becomes subject to intense media attention.
This may produce dramatic changes. Consistent with
this explanation, Jones, Baumgartner & True (1998)
find that dramatic changes occur, and that they
cannot be explained simply by exogenous shocks,
and Danish and UK data show that leptokurtosis is
more prevalent in some policy areas than in others.
The authors suggest that explanations for this might
be factors such as international conflict and party
preferences (John and Margetts, 2003: 427).
Explanations based on the interplay between
political subsystems and the macro political arena
and on information processing are definitely
relevant, and account for empirical variation in the
amount of leptokurtosis. But one puzzle is still left.
If the avalanches are caused by the differences in
institutions, in policy areas, in media attention or
due to friction or to over-emphasis on certain signals
from the outside world, how come that avalanches
seems to be omnipresent? The empirical studies
show that budget changes nearly always follow a
leptokurtic distribution. If these factors were the
only possible causes of this phenomenon, should we
not expect it not to occur in some instances?
In the following, we identify four simple
characteristics, which must apply to any budgeting
process. We argue that complex patterns of policy
punctuations is a result of these four characteristics
alone, and develop a simulation which show that this
is indeed true. Specifically, we hypothesize that,
even in a system with no outside intervention, with
perfectly normally distributed input signals, with no
overemphasis on certain signals, no institutions, and
with no friction, leptokurtosis will, due to interaction
among multiple agents, still prevail. This conjecture
is based on the following four simple observations,
which must be true of any budgeting process.
Without someone requesting and allocating funding,
there would be no budgeting activity at all (Schick,
1988: 63). Therefore, in any budgeting process:
(1) Several actors (beggars) request and spend
budgets
(2) Several actors (philanthropists) allocate funding
Funding is requested partly because any
organization or program needs some resources to
survive; insufficient funding will, at some point, lead
to closure or radical transformation. Programs,
institutions, agencies, or other entities which depend
on public money which do not receive sufficient
funding will eventually close down. This means that:
(3) Beggars which do not receive sufficient funding
will eventually close down
Budgeting is about allocating resources between
several different purposes. This means that any
budgeting process involves several different actors
requesting funding, and there is always a possibility
that new ideas or programs will appear. Finally,
budgeting is only relevant if funding is limited and
smaller than the sum of all requests for funding. If
this were not the case, money could just be
distributed, and budgeting would not be relevant at
all. This completes the list of the four observations:
(4) Available funding is limited and often smaller
than requested funding
Therefore, in budgeting, actors are
interdependent. This is easy to see. Since funding is
SIMULTECH 2012 - 2nd International Conference on Simulation and Modeling Methodologies, Technologies and
Applications
98
limited (4), some actors request funding (1) from a
closed set of funding opportunities (2), and is
required to do so in order to survive (3), the fate of
one particular actor in the budgeting process
depends on how successful others are. If there are
many competitors, and if they receive a very large
share of the available funding, it is harder to get
sufficient funding. If competitors collapse or
disappear, more resources will be available for
others. The four simple observations therefore imply
that budgeting takes place in a complex
interdependent system. Interestingly, complex
systems of interdependent parts tend to produce
leptokurtic distributions. This happens when
complex systems during prolonged periods of
relative stability self-organize into a critical state.
When in a critical state, the system is likely to
experience a major change.
This brief account of budgeting and complexity
does not, of course, substantiate the claim that the
four simple observations on budgeting imply
leptokurtosis. In order to do this, we simulate a
simple budgeting game adhering to the four
observations.
2 THE SIMULATION
In our simulation some actors, called beggars, are
capable of applying for funding from several
possible sources, which are called philanthropists.
Beggars seek to optimize their appropriations.
Beggars and philanthropists obey a set of simple and
minimalist rules which are congruent with the four
observations. All input into the simulation is drawn
randomly from a normal distribution. The question
is then whether the output is also normally
distributed or leptokurtic.
In this section the simulation is described. We begin
with a verbal explanation of the basic logic in the
simulation, and how it can be interpreted. We then
schematically present it in more detail.
Beggars and philanthropists interact as shown in
Figure 2. First, beggars request funding (point 1 of
the observations). They spend money and generate
(or use) savings. Second, philanthropists allocate
funding among applicants and send appropriations
(point 2). If appropriations continue to fall short of
spending, savings of the beggar will eventually be
exhausted. The beggar then closes down and
disappears (point 3). Philanthropists have limited
possibilities to provide funding, and there is always
a demand from beggars of funding (point 4).
Budget requirement
Spending
Savings
Available funding
Budget request
Appropriation
Beggar
Philanthropist
Figure 2: The relation between a beggar and a
philanthropist.
The chances of getting funding depends the
familiarity of a beggar to a philanthropist. This is
modeled spatially. The beggars and philanthropists
are located in a grid of, say, the size 10 x 10. This
gives 100 possible locations. The various locations
of the philanthropists in space can be interpreted as
their association with a certain sector, with certain
types of projects, or a certain policy area. If a beggar
is close to a philanthropist, it means that the
proposal of the beggar seems relevant and familiar
from the perspective of the philanthropist. The
distance from a beggar to a philanthropist represents
familiarity. For instance, an interpretation of a
beggar being located next to a philanthropist would
be that the beggar provides a service, which is well
known to and highly prioritized by the
philanthropist. Conversely, a beggar located far
away from any philanthropist is trying to get funding
for a really arcane project or purpose, which no
philanthropist is likely to prefer to support.
A beggar can only apply for funding from one
philanthropist. Beggars move in order to be close to
an attractive philanthropist, but movement is
penalized. Moving is tantamount to redefining or
reformulating the funding proposal in order to
accommodate a new philanthropist. The distance
moved to be located next to a philanthropist
therefore affects the opportunity to get funding. If a
beggar does not have to move, it is well known by
the philanthropist and is therefore likely to get
funding. If a beggar must move a long distance, it is
less likely to get funding. If a beggar has moved a
long distance, the philanthropist will be more likely
to consider cutting the budget request. This happens
when the beggar is selected for review. If the beggar
has moved the maximum possible distance, the
beggar will always be selected. If the beggar has not
moved since the last iteration, the risk of review is
equal to the base risk at 50%. As we return to below,
this, and other central values can be varied. We
systematically vary these parameters in our analysis
to check the robustness of the results.
If a beggar received all requested funding in last
iteration, the beggar stays with the philanthropist. If
not, the beggar seeks for a more attractive
philanthropist. The beggars find the most attractive
A Really Simple Explanation of Policy Punctuations? - Interdependence, Complexity, and Policy Punctuations
99
philanthropist, move if necessary, and receive
funding. If funding is insufficient, savings are
reduced, and if saving fall below zero, the beggar
disappears. If funding is sufficient, the beggar starts
over in the next iteration. The philanthropists receive
applications, and allocate appropriations.
In the first three stages, the simulation is
initialized. The action takes place in the remaining
six stages, which are repeated in a large number of
iterations. In the first stage of the simulation the n ×
n grid is created. The size of the grid is determined
by a parameter called [Size]. In the second and third
stage, several beggars and philanthropists are
created. For each beggar, a budget to be requested is
determined; for each philanthropist, funding to
allocate is determined, both random numbers drawn
from a normal distribution with a specific mean and
standard deviation (both are parameters). The exact
number of beggars and philanthropists are set as
parameters. Their location in the grid is determined
randomly. This completes the initialization in the
first three stages.
The action takes place in the remaining six
stages. These stages are iterated a large number of
times. In stage four, budget needs are determined for
each beggar. This is the amount the beggar will
spend. Budget needs is a fraction of the budget
requirements, calculated as a random number from a
normal distribution with mean 0.98 times the budget
requirement. Beggars then select a philanthropist. If
a beggar in the previous iteration got full finding, it
will stick to the same philanthropist as in last
iteration. If not, it will locate visible philanthropists,
and choose the most attractive one, based on a
calculation of the expected payoff for each visible
philanthropist.
In stage five, funding is allocated. The
philanthropists collect the budget requests, and
determine whether the available funding is
sufficient. If it is, the beggars get what they request.
If the sum of requests for funding exceeds the
amount available, the philanthropist will select
beggars for review. The likelihood of being selected
is base risk (a parameter) at 50% + a movement
penalty. If no beggars were selected, the procedure
is repeated. In stage six, the beggars spend money
according to the budget needs. The surplus (or
deficit) of a beggar is added to its savings. In stage
seven, the state of the world is printed to a file.
Beggars with negative savings are eliminated. In
stage eight, new beggars are generated if the sum of
available resources exceeds the sum of requested
funding. In stage nine, the positions of the beggars
are updated, and the budget requests of each beggar
changes by a random number drawn from a normal
distribution. The beggars and philanthropists then
start over at stage four in the next iteration.
3 THE DISTRIBUTION OF
BUDGET CHANGES
We now analyze the distribution of changes in
appropriations in subsets of different sizes. The
smallest subset consists of 9% of the grid. On
average, such an area encompasses 4-5
philanthropists and 18-20 beggars. The beggars, of
course, may have options outside of the area, and are
able to move in and out. For the 9%-subset, Figure 3
shows a histogram for changes in appropriations for
the default parameters in a simulation with 10,000
iterations with a superimposed normal distribution
with same mean and standard deviation as the
distribution of changes in appropriations. A visual
inspection reveals that the distribution is non-
normal. Changes in appropriations tend to have a
higher peak, and more dramatic changes occur than
would be expected from a normal distribution.
Similar simulations have been carried out for 959
other configurations of parameters.
0
.5
1
1.5
Density
-1 0 1 2 3
Percent change in appropriations
Figure 3: Histogram for changes in appropriation for 9%-
subset. Standard parameters.
On average, the l-kurtosis value for these 960
distributions is 0.203. This is clearly higher than the
l-kurtosis score for the normal distribution. Hence,
in the smallest subset, the typical distribution is
leptokurtic. However, it is not always the case. Of
the 960 simulations, 1% has distributions below
0.112, and 5% below 0.124. Although it is quite
rare, and although l-kurtosis values are typically
above 0.1226 (the value for a normal distribution),
some of the simulations end up with normal or even
SIMULTECH 2012 - 2nd International Conference on Simulation and Modeling Methodologies, Technologies and
Applications
100
almost uniform distributions.
Figure 4 shows average l-kurtosis scores for
different subsets. It is clear the l-kurtosis score is
negatively related to the size of the subset. The
figure shows the average l-kurtosis scores (0.203 for
the 9% subset) along with the scores for the 25th and
75th percentiles. The horizontal line shows the l-
kurtosis scores for a normal distribution. As the
subset becomes larger, the l-kurtosis scores drop.
They are always, also at the system level where
100% of the grid is analyzed) on average above the
score of a normal distribution, but when the subset is
larger than 50%, only slightly so. The percentile
spikes indicate that it becomes increasingly common
that some of the simulations, even though the
average is above 0.1226, fall below the score of the
normal distribution.
Hence, the simulations show that leptokurtosis is
quite common in analyses of subsets of the system,
and that the l-kurtosis scores are quite low compared
to empirical distributions of budget changes.
Furthermore, the tendency to leptokurtosis becomes
smaller when for larger subsets, and almost
disappears at the system level. We infer from this
that leptokurtosis at the subsystem level is almost
always a consequence of the four simple
observations that we argue must be true of any
budgeting process. We also infer that the four
observations cannot account for the much larger l-
kurtosis scores typically observed in empirical
distributions. Hence, the four simple observations
can account for why leptokurtosis is omnipresent,
but they cannot account for the magnitude of
leptokurtosis.
.12 .14 .16 .18
.2
.22
0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Size
Percentile75/Percentile25 lkurtosis
NormalDist
Figure 4: L-kurtosis scores for different subsets. 960
simulations with varying parameters.
This is consistent with the empirical findings that
leptokurtosis is an fact systematically related to
factors such as different features of policy areas,
characteristics of information processing, differences
in decision costs, and variations in the institutional
setting (Jones & Baumgartner, 2005a; 2005b;
Breunig, 2007; Jones, Sulkin and Larsen, 2003;
Breunig and Koski, 2006). All of these factors are
held constant in this simulation. What are not held
constant are the parameters. The analyses are based
on 960 simulations with different configuration of
parameters.
4 CONCLUSIONS
We know quite a lot on how public budgets change.
They tend, most of the time, to be remarkably stable.
This is the classical instrumentalist insight.
However, an equally important part of budgeting is
that, once in a while, very large changes occur.
Changes in budgets follow a leptokurtic distribution.
This seems to be an omnipresent phenomenon. In
this paper we conjecture that leptokurtosis is a very
fundamental feature of public budgeting. We argue
that four simple observations, that should be true of
any budgeting process, are enough to account for
leptokurtosis. We investigate the implications of the
four observations by designing a simple simulation
of a budgeting game between beggars and
philanthropists adhering to the observations. It turns
out that the four observations do in fact imply
leptokurtosis at the subsystem level. However, the
observations and the simulation do not predict as
large l-kurtosis scores as is typically found in
empirical distributions of changes in budgets.
Ockham’s razor seems, in this case, to be too blunt
an instrument. This leads us to conclude that
leptokurtosis is in fact a very fundamental feature of
public budgeting, and that this is likely to be part of
the explanation of why leptokurtosis is omnipresent.
However, it is only part of the explanation. To
understand differences in leptokurtosis and the
magnitude of leptokurtosis, other explanations are
necessary. Fortunately, these explanations are
available in the empirically based literature on
policy punctuations and budgeting.
REFERENCES
Bak P. (1996). How Nature Works. New York: Copernicus
Baumgartner, Frank R. & Bryan D. Jones (1993). Agendas
and Instability in American Politics, Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Baumgartner, Frank R., Martial Foucault & Abel François
(2006): “Punctuated equilibrium in French budgeting
A Really Simple Explanation of Policy Punctuations? - Interdependence, Complexity, and Policy Punctuations
101
processes”, Journal of European Public Policy, vol.
13 (7), pp. 1086-1103.
Breunig, C. and C. Koski (2006): “Punctuated Equilibria
and Budgets in the American States”, Policy Studies
Journal, 34 (3), 2006.
Breunig, Christian (2007). Institutions, Attention Shifts,
and changes within National Budgets, Ph.D.-
dissertation, University of Washington.
Davis, Otto A., M. A. H. Dempster and Aaron Wildavsky
(1966): “A Theory of the Budgetary Process”,
American Political Science Review 60 (3), 1966
John, P. and H. Margetts (2003): “Policy Punctuations in
the UK: Fluctuations and Equilibria in Central
Government Expenditure since 1951”, Public
Administration, 81 (3), 2003.
Jones, B. D., F. R. Baumgartner and J. L. True (1998):
“Policy Punctuations: US Budget Authority, 1947
95”, Journal of Politics, 60, 1998.
Jones, B. D., T. Sulkin & H. A. Larsen (2003): “Policy
Punctuations in American Political Institutions”;
American Political Science Review 97 (1), 2003
Jones, Bryan D. & Frank Baumgartner (2005a): ”A Model
of Choice for Public Policy”, Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory, vol 15, pp. 325-
351.
Jones, Bryan D. & Frank Baumgartner (2005b): The
Politics of Attention, Chicago: Chicago University
Press.
Padgett, J. F. (1980): “Bounded Rationality in Budgetary
Research”, American Political Science Review, 74,
1980.
Schick, Allen (1988). “En Enquiry into the Possibility of a
Budgetary Theory”, in Rubin, Irene S. (ed.), New
Directions in Budgetary Theory, New York: State
University of New York Press.
True, J. L. (2000): “Avalanches and Incrementalism:
Making Policy and Budgets in the United States”,
American Review of Public Administration, 30 (1),
2000.
Wildavsky, A. (1984): The Politics of the Budgetary
Process. Little, Brown and Company, Boston.
SIMULTECH 2012 - 2nd International Conference on Simulation and Modeling Methodologies, Technologies and
Applications
102