Households’ Behaviors and Systemic Financial Instability
Experimental Insights and Agent-based Simulations
for Macroeconomic Policy Analyses
Paola D’Orazio
Department of Economic-Quantitative and Philosophical-Educational Sciences
University “G. D’Annunzio” Chieti-Pescara, viale Pindaro, 42, 65127 Pescara, Italy
1 OBJECTIVES AND STAGE OF
THE RESEARCH
In the last two years my research has focused on
macroeconomic financial fragility. In particular, on
how to bring different methodologies together to
study endogenous generated crises
1
.
Economics profession is currently engaged in a de-
bate on which are the best methodological tools in or-
der to study the dynamics of the real economy and
adequately address important policy issues and so-
cial concerns. My research endorse the view accord-
ing to which traditional economic theories and the
models they give rise to (namely, the DSGE models)
are ill-equipped to manage serious crises which of-
ten emerge in real world economies. In my research
project I am trying to address these issues by develop-
ing an “experimentally” microfounded Agent-based
model (ABM), which will account also for the con-
sistency of stocks and flows
2
.
The main research issues concern both the micro and
the macro level, i.e., agents and the environment in
which they act and interact. For the micro level, I have
designed an experiment in order to gain insights into
agents’ behaviors. For the macro level, I plan to build
an ABM where agents are estimated - rather than cal-
ibrated - by using experimental data.
3
I plan to start
working on the Agent-based macro structure once fin-
ished the micro level analysis, i.e. (a) performing the
experiment and data analysis and (b) building the be-
1
Endogenous crises are those generated caeteris paribus
by non-price interactions, localized learning processes, in-
vestment practices. For a more comprehensive analysis of
financial fragility and its effects on real economy see (Min-
sky, 1970, 1974, 1992).
2
This is a relevant aspect of the model that will be built.
Detailed explanation and motivations for this requirement
are given in 2.3. For an historical and methodological per-
spective on Stock-Flow consistency nad related models see
(Caverzasi and Godin, 2013).
3
This point is explained in section 4.
havioral rules for artificial agents. Once the ABM will
be set up, I will perform policy experiments in order
to evaluate the effectiveness and “profitability” of dif-
ferent policies.
2 RESEARCH PROBLEM
The interest in this research originates from the in-
creasingly widespread opinion among scholars who
claim for the need of new tools to cope with the com-
plexity of socio-economic systems. The new tools
must be able to allow for the building of microfoun-
dations of Macroeconomics by considering also the
feedback effect the macro system has on individual
agents. Analytically solvable pure theoretical macro
models are of little help for policy guidance (Velupil-
lai, 2011) because they are based on assumptions that
are far from reality and do not consider any interac-
tion among heterogeneous agents (Kirman, 1992). In
order to consider the macro economy as a complex
endogenously organized system, researchers should
be able to study both the micro level, i.e., agents, and
the macro level, i.e., the environment. Concerning
the former, behaviors that guides the decision-making
process and the heterogeneity of agents’ population
must be incorporated into the model. Regarding the
latter, models have to deal with the complexity and
instability of the macro environment, which is indeed
a central feature of the choices that economic agents
face.
2.1 The Micro Level
As Simon argued in 1959, to explain agents’ behavior
in the face of complexity, the theory must incorporate
at least some description of the processes and mech-
anisms through which the adaptation takes place. Si-
mon claimed that the emergence of new areas of the-
ory and application, in which complexity and change
are central facts, led to the demand for a fuller picture
15
D’Orazio P..
Households’ Behaviors and Systemic Financial Instability - Experimental Insights and Agent-based Simulations for Macroeconomic Policy Analyses.
Copyright
c
2014 SCITEPRESS (Science and Technology Publications, Lda.)
of economic man (Simon, 1959).
The behavioral revolution” (Akerlof, 2002; Kahne-
man, 2003; Camerer et al., 2004), which has unfolded
in recent decades following in Simon’s footsteps, has
contributed to the increase of the explanatory power
of Economics by providing it with more realistic psy-
chological foundations and “practical” ways in which
behaviors can be incorporated into the models (Kao
and Velupillai, 2011).
2.2 The Macro Level
The second problem of the present research is related
to the definition of the economy as a Complex Adap-
tive System (Tesfatsion, 2003).
ABMs allow to study the “micro-to-macro map-
ping” (Epstein, 2007) as well as social complexity.
They are indeed flexible, precise and consistent mod-
eling tool, providing the ability to explore learning
and adaptation phenomena and increasing our under-
standing of economic dynamics (Holland and Miller,
1991). In their “early steps” (LeBaron, 2000), ABMs
have been mainly used as a tool to scale up to the
macro level and to perform counterintuitive hypothe-
ses regarding individual behavior or to gain insights
into existing human experiments.
However, as Epstein (2007) points out, “even per-
fect knowledge of individual decision rules does not
always allow us to predict macroscopic structure”.
The microspecification of the ABM is thus crucial:
individual behaviors “observed in the experimental
laboratory become the solid foundationsof the model.
Moreover, information collected from experimental
micro-systems differs from that obtained from empir-
ical data (Smith, 1982) in that the former offers richer
insights into the individual and collective dynamics
of a model. Experimental data could thus represent a
solution to the problem of availability of micro data
which threatens the research on the microfoundations
of macroeconomic models (Carroll, 2012b).
2.3 The Stock-Flow Consistency
Requirement
Adding a stock-flow consistency (SFC) requirement
to the model helps to overcome the fallacy of compo-
sition critique
4
. Moreover, it helps in detecting sec-
toral instability - the household sector in the present
research project - by considering agents’ balance
sheets.
4
It concerns the presumption that what is true of each
single part of a whole is necessarily true of the whole as
well. Basically, it questions the aggregation process used
by “standard” macroeconomic models.
SFC models are specific kinds of macro models
that try to coherently integrate all stocks and flows of
an economy. The two main components are: (1) the
accounting framework, and (2) the behavioral equa-
tions. The first of these two components usually relies
on a set of matrices reproducing the balance sheets,
the transactions, and the capital gains of each of the
institutional sectors into which the economy is orga-
nized. The second component is a set of behavioral
equations modeling all the transactions not directly
determined by the accounting structure of the econ-
omy.
Their roots lie in the study on “money flows” of
Morris A. Copeland (Copeland, 1949, 1962)
5
. Re-
cently, SFC models are drawing new attention by re-
searchers in that they are developing new ways to use
the SFC framework as a development of the exist-
ing general aggregative models (Kinsella et al., 2011;
Seppecher, 2012; Raberto et al., 2012).
Until now SFC models are designed as systems
of stock-flow consistent equations describing the laws
of motion of the economy at the aggregate level.
The combination of SFC and Agent-based modeling
tools will yield more complete macro models. On
one hand, the ABM can display consistency between
stocks and flows; the result is a framework that en-
sures the compatibility of real and financial variables.
On the other hand, the ABM provide explicit micro-
foundations to macroeconomic relations.
3 STATE OF THE ART
Agent-based models have been used to study findings
from human subject experiments. In his review, Duffy
(2006) calls the attention on the interaction between
ABM and Experimental Economics by claiming that
they are “natural allies”. He points out three main ar-
eas in which ABM have been used in this way. The
first one is the so-called zero-intelligent agent ap-
proach based on the Gode and Sunder (1991) seminal
paper. It consists of models with very low rational-
ity constraints which made evident that self-interested
and rational behavior is observed mainly in highly
structured and constrained markets. A second line of
research focuses on reinforcerment and belief-based
models of agents’ behaviors. Finally, there are Evolu-
tionary Algorithms where individual learning is more
5
The intuition of Copeland was to enlarge the social ac-
counting perspective - which had been used mainly in the
study of national income - to the study of money flows. He
laid the foundations for an economic approach able to in-
tegrate real and financial ows of the economy (Copeland
(1949), p. 254).
ICAART2014-DoctoralConsortium
16
complicated.
Brian Arthur was among the firsts in exploring the
idea of calibrating an algorithm to reproduce human
behavior (Arthur, 1991, 1993). He called the atten-
tion on the need to go beyond the assumption of ra-
tionality, suggesting some ways to model economic
choices. He did not want to design a learning algo-
rithm or automaton that maximizes some criterion.
Rather, he aimed at designing an algorithm that can
be “tuned to choose actions in an iterated choice sit-
uation the way humans would ”(Arthur, 1991, p.354).
To calibrate the algorithm in a way that could be de-
fined as a “good indication” of human behavior, he
used the results of an experiment performed in 1952-
53 by Robillard at Harvard University. His results
- and tests of fitness - showed that the automaton
was able to replicate those behaviors also in differ-
ent choice problems, than those for which it was cali-
brated.
From Arthur on, Genetic Algorithm (GA) has
been extensively used in Economics; simulations’
results show GAs successfully replicate experimen-
tal behaviors in different environments (see Arifovic,
1996, 2000; Dawid, 1996, for a comprehensive sur-
vey). However, in the ABM literature artificial agents
have usually been considered as equally smart”
(Chen and Yu, 2011) and they are built by relying on
available theories on individual decision-making (see
Raberto et al., 2012; Dosi et al., 2010, 2013, among
others). The exploration and induction of agents’ be-
haviors by means of the experimental method is thus
a more recent strand of research.
4 METHODOLOGY
Households’ financial behaviors (in particular, their
“debt love”/debt aversion) will be put under the “mag-
nifying glass” by means of the experimental method
in order to detect flaws in traditional theories of in-
tertemporal consumption/saving decisions. The ex-
perimental method will allow also to explore actual
decision-making processes and heterogeneity across
agents. Data collected from experiments will be used
to analyze the aggregate implications of households’
behaviors and to eventually estimate the behaviors of
artificial agents that will interact in the artificial envi-
ronment. As showed in Giulioni et al. (2013), the use
of experimental data allows to go beyond the standard
parameters’ calibration procedure.
The household sector will be included in a broader
project, i.e. a macroeconomic ABM, in which the
firm sector and the banking sector will be also consid-
ered. The “integrated” experimental-ABM methodol-
ogy will allow studying both how the macro dynam-
ics evolve and the eventual endogenously generated
crises.
4.1 Experimental Insights on
Intertemporal Decision-making
Experimental Economics complements computa-
tional, theoretical and empirical works (Davis and
Holt, 1993; Binmore, 1999; Samuelson, 2005) in that
it helps identifying behavioral rules agents use in eco-
nomic decision-making (Kahneman, 2003). Indeed,
the experimentation process is not a “simple” addi-
tional element of the modeling process; rather it inter-
acts at a deeper level with the limited cognitive abili-
ties of economic agents.
Several studies have been highlighting that indi-
vidual preferences - and macro feedbacks - are ob-
servable and controllable in the laboratory such that
economic modeling becomes richer and more realis-
tic (Smith, 1982, 2002). In this sense, the experimen-
tal approach follows both the warnings of the well-
known Lucas’ critique (Lucas, 1986) and the Lucas’
invitation
6
. In his “invitation”, Lucas stresses the rel-
evance of experiments in shedding light on humans
decision making processes, and therefore on the eco-
nomic analysis as a whole.
In my research, experiments are used to closely in-
vestigate human behaviors in an attempt to contribute
to the research stream concerned with the building
of new microfoundations for macroeconomic models.
This method also allows for “detecting agents het-
erogeneity and how they interact with each other.
4.1.1 The Experimental Design: Some
Theoretical and Methodological
Considerations
The designed experiment will address two issues in
intertemporal consumption models. On one side, the
experimental approach will allow to investigate the
ability of subjects to solve the task of intertempo-
ral optimization and the extent to which subjects be-
have according to standard optimization rules (Car-
roll, 1996, 2012b). In this way, the experiment will
take the theoretical predictions seriously and test if
consumers are able to carry out a dynamic intertem-
poral (utility) optimization problem. On the other
side, the experimental method will be used to study
the pervasiveness of debt in the liabilities side of
households’ portfolios. The model will thus account
6
As described in the Experimental Economics entry in
the New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (Duffy, 2008).
Households'BehaviorsandSystemicFinancialInstability-ExperimentalInsightsandAgent-basedSimulationsfor
MacroeconomicPolicyAnalyses
17
also for the role financial innovations have been gain-
ing in capitalistic economies in the last decades.
The experimental design is grounded on methods
and results of the early experiments performed on in-
tertemporal consumption. The first attempt of testing
how closely the predictions of the optimality theory
fit the actual behavior of subjects in an experimental
setting is the paper by Hey and Dardanoni (1987). My
experiment is closely related to the more recent exper-
iment performed by Ballinger et al. (2003) (although
I do not focus on intergenerational learning) and it
is designed in the footprints of the “learning to opti-
mize” experiments (LtOEs) where subjects are asked
to directly make economic decisions (to consume, in-
vest, trade, produce, etc.)
7
.
4.1.2 The Experimental Design: The Model
The starting point is the building of a benchmark
intertemporal consumption model which is used to
compute the optimal (theoretical) solution that will be
compared to our experimental data in order to assess
if there is a deviation from the optimal behavior. The
major innovation introduced concerns the relaxation
of the standard budget constraint by allowing borrow-
ing, hence debt.
The solution for the intertemporal consumption
problem is found by backward induction, following
the method for microeconomic dynamic stochastic
optimization problems. Among others, we consid-
ered the methods developed by Carroll (2012a) and
Stachurski (2009). Given that an explicit solution
to the problem does not exist (it is implicitly char-
acterised by an Euler equation), numerical methods
are needed in order to find an optimal policy func-
tion (for saving and borrowing tasks) to be compared
to subjects’ decisions in the lab. This methodologi-
cal choice is of particular importance because in the
experiment we should be able to control for all possi-
ble confounding factors and focus on few variables of
interest.
For the standard intertemporal consumption
model set up, I compute the policy function for a con-
sumption/saving task which in turn will be used as a
benchmark for experimental data.
In order to have a simple and tractable model I
do not consider the discount factor; a separate exper-
iment is necessary in order to elicit - thus estimate -
the discount parameter of subjects in the lab. I indeed
7
LtOEs differ from “learning-to-forecast” experiments
(LtFEs) in that LtFEs aim atelicitating subjects’ forecasts of
the relevant endogenous variables such as the market price,
interest rate or wages. See, Arifovic (1996) and Smith et al.
(1988).
decided to leave this investigation for another exper-
iment (Cubitt and Read, 2007; Coller and Williams,
1999; Harrison et al., 1995).
The intertemporal settings that will be ana-
lyzed will be basically two. The perfect certainty
model (deterministic) which would be the ”candi-
date” framework to test the predictions of the model
built on the rational expectations assumptions, and a
stochastic version in which there is uncertainty about
the future income stream. The latter will be useful to
assess which kind of expectations (adaptive, etc) arise
among experimental subjects.
Th experimental subject pool will be composed by
students and workers
8
in an attempt to address the
usual criticism about the external validity of experi-
mental data and results.
4.2 The Economy as a Complex Adaptive
System
Agent-based modeling is of particual interest for
my research since it allows for taking into account
the possibility of endogenous co-evolution of micro-
behaviors and institutions (namely, the macro struc-
ture), the heterogeneity and interactions among eco-
nomic agents that can lead the system to breakdown
without external interference, i.e., shocks. In this,
ABMs are a versatile tool: observed dynamics are
open-ended (not closed form) and they allow for an
ergodic state of the system, i.e., an equilibrium, which
is an emergent and optional outcome (Delli Gatti
et al., 2008). While DSGE models are based on the
centralized information processing structure, ABM
takes a bottom-up approach that starts modelling real-
istic microfoundations and ends up analyzing the re-
sulting aggregate behaviour. The dynamics of aggre-
gate variables are the result of complex, continuously
and endogenously changing micro-structure. This
yields substantial advantages in modelling macroeco-
nomic policies (LeBaron and Tesfatsion, 2008).
However, there are some methodological prob-
lems related to ABM. Caeteris paribus, the empir-
ical model validation
9
and robustness checks of re-
sults. Indeed, the large flexibility of the setup (start-
ing values) of agent-based models and the number of
selected parameters give many “degrees of freedom”
to the researcher. This in turn poses serious chal-
lenges to the use of ACE models for the evaluation
and design of economic policy measures. This prob-
lem could be (partially) overcome by using the ex-
8
They have been recruited throught the ORSEE software
(Greiner, 2004).
9
For a broader discussion on this issue see (Fagiolo
et al., 2007a,b).
ICAART2014-DoctoralConsortium
18
perimental method to build (i.e., estimate) agents that
populate the artificial environment.
4.3 Genetic Algorithm “Revisited”
The application and development of the methodology
presented and discussed in this paper benefits mainly
from theoretical and “practical” insights of Brock and
Hommes (1997) seminal paper. It is also inspired
from the improvements of “heuristics switching mod-
els”, in which agents have a set of imple forecasting
heuristics (adaptive, trend extrapolating and so on)
and choose those that had a better past performance.
However, in order to account for a “complete”
agents’ heteroegeneity and give the model better mi-
crofoundations, the researcher needs tools that allow
to consider the whole set of behavioral rules finded in
experimental data. In the last decades, many schoars
have been engaged in this line of research so that het-
erogenous, interacting agents in ABM are designed in
many different ways (for a comprehensive survey see
Chen (2012)).
At the present stage of my research I am consid-
ering retaking Brian Arthurs main arguments and re-
sults (as discussed in section 3) and go beyond the cal-
ibration process by estimating the behavioral rules for
artificial agents. Indeed, the main point of the present
research project is that by means of the experimental
method it is possible to gain insights into human be-
havior and collect information on heterogeneity of the
population. Experimental data can thus be used to es-
timate, rather than “merely” calibrate, the behavioral
rules that guide artificial agents’ actions
10
.
In order to fit the ABM using experimental data, I
am considering the implementation of a Genetic Al-
gorithm, Classifier Systems or a combination of both.
GA is a flexible optimization procedure which has
been extensively used in Economics (Arifovic, 2000,
1996). Classifier systems is a machine learning sys-
tem that learns syntactically simple string rules, called
classifiers (Booker et al., 1989; Birchenhall, 1995).
The decision will come after a comparison and careful
analysis of the pros and cons - ad the related effective-
ness - of the application of the two techniques to the
problem under scrutiny.
In the evaluation of which evolutionary method
and technique will best fit for my project, I am
also concerned about the economic soundness of this
tools. I am indeed considering both the concerns
and the warning of Waltman et al. (2011); Dawid and
10
Hansen and Heckman (1996) offer an interesting per-
spective on model calibration and estimation methodolo-
gies. It also discusses the related empirical “hidden dan-
gers”.
Dermietzel (2006) about the economic interpretation
of evolutionary algorithms based on binary encoding
and other techniques adopted from computer science
without any modification.
5 TIMING AND EXPECTED
OUTCOME
The research presented in this paper represents a doc-
toral research project which is still in progress. It
benefits from the integration of different methodolo-
gies and modeling techniques. The last 2 years have
been devoted to the study of both the experimental
and the agent-based methods and to figure how they
can benefit from each other in order to build a macro
model. The experimental phase is ready to be imple-
mented; once performed I will use experimental data
to build the behavioral rules for artificial agents and
thus populate the artificial economy, i.e., the ABM.
The expected outcome of the present research is in-
deed the development of an “integrated” methodol-
ogy of research which is based on the interaction of
Agent-based modeling tools and Experimental Eco-
nomics method, with the “additional” requirement of
SFC.
The combined use of Experimental Economics
method and Agent-based Computational Economics,
enriched by the “informed intuition” of stock-flow
consistency, will allow to develop more real-like
macro models and more practical tools to guide pol-
icymakers. The ABM will be then used to perform
some policy experiments, i.e., analyses on the effects
and effectiveness of different fiscal and/or monetary
policies. The problem of availability of micro data
(Carroll, 2012b) for a “proper” estimation of agents’
behavioral rules will be overcome by relying on data
collected from experiments. Finally, the present re-
search is also aiming at contributing to the improve-
ment of the ABMs’ calibration/estimation techniques.
REFERENCES
Akerlof, G. A. (2002). Behavioral macroeconomics and
macroeconomic behavior. American Economic Re-
view, 92(3):411–433.
Arifovic, J. (1996). The behavior of the exchange rate in the
genetic algorithm and experimental economies. Jour-
nal of Political Economy, 104(3):510–41.
Arifovic, J. (2000). Evolutionary algorithms in macroe-
conomic models. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 4:373–
414.
Arthur, W. B. (1991). Designing Economic Agents that
Act like Human Agents: A Behavioral Approach to
Households'BehaviorsandSystemicFinancialInstability-ExperimentalInsightsandAgent-basedSimulationsfor
MacroeconomicPolicyAnalyses
19
Bounded Rationality. American Economic Review Pa-
pers and Proceedings, 81(2):353–359.
Arthur, W. B. (1993). On designing economic agents that
behave like human agents. Journal of Ecolutionary
Economics, 3:1–22.
Ballinger, T. P., Palumbo, M. G., and Wilcox, N. T.
(2003). Precautionary saving and social learning
across generations: an experiment. Economic Jour-
nal, 113(490):920–947.
Binmore, K. (1999). Why Experiment in Economics? Eco-
nomic Journal, 109(453):16–24.
Birchenhall, C. R. (1995). Genetic algorithms, classifier
systems and genetic programming and their use in the
models of adaptive behaviour and learning. The Eco-
nomic Journal, 105(430):788–795.
Booker, L. B., Goldberg, D. E., and Holland, J. H. (1989).
Classifier systems and genetic algorithms. Artificial
Intelligence, 40(1-3):235–282.
Brock, W. A. and Hommes, C. H. (1997). A rational route
to randomness. Econometrica, 65(5):1059–1096.
Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., and Rabin, M. (2004). Ad-
vances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton Univer-
sity Press, Princeton.
Carroll, C. (2012a). Lecture notes on solution methods for
microeconomicdynamic stochastic optimization prob-
lems. Lecture Notes - John Hopkins University.
Carroll, C. D. (1996). Buffer-stock saving and the life cy-
cle/permanent income hypothesis. NBER Working
Papers 5788, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Inc.
Carroll, C. D. (2012b). Representing consumption and sav-
ing without a representative consumer. In Measuring
Economic Sustainability and Progress, NBER Chap-
ters. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Caverzasi, E. and Godin, A. (2013). Stock-flow consistent
modeling through the ages. Economics working paper
archive, Levy Economics Institute, The.
Chen, S.-H. (2012). Varieties of agents in agent-based com-
putational economics: A historical and an interdisci-
plinary perspective. Journal of Economic Dynamics
and Control, 36(1):1–25.
Chen, S.-H. and Yu, T. (2011). Agents learned, but
do we? knowledge discovery using the agent-based
double auction markets. In Frontiers of Electrical
and Electronic Engineering in China, pages 159–170.
Springer.
Coller, M. and Williams, M. (1999). Eliciting individual
discount rates. Experimental Economics, 2(2):107–
127.
Copeland, M. A. (1949). Social accounting for moneyflows.
The Accounting Review, page 254264.
Copeland, M. A. (1962). Some illustrative analytical uses of
flow-of-funds data. In The Flow-of Funds Approach to
Social Accounting, pages 195–238. National Bureau
of Economic Research, Inc.
Cubitt, R. and Read, D. (2007). Can intertemporal choice
experiments elicit time preferences for consumption?
Experimental Economics, 10:369–89.
Davis, D. D. and Holt, C. A. (1993). Experimental eco-
nomics: Methods, problems and promise. Estudios
Economicos, 8(2):179–212.
Dawid, H. (1996). Adaptive Learning by Genetic Algo-
rithms: Analytical Results and Applications to Eco-
nomic Models. Springer Verlag New York, Inc.
Dawid, H. and Dermietzel, J. (2006). How robust is the
equal split norm? responsive strategies, selection
mechanisms and the need for economic interpretation
of simulation parameters. Computational Economics,
28(4).
Delli Gatti, D., Gaffeo, E., Gallegati, M., Giulioni, G.,
and Palestrini, A. (2008). Emergent Macroeconomics.
Springer Verlag, Berlin.
Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., Napoletano, M., and Roventini, A.
(2013). Income distribution, credit and fiscal policies
in an agent-based keynesian model. Journal of Eco-
nomic Dynamics and Control, 37(8):1598–1625.
Dosi, G., Fagiolo, G., and Roventini, A. (2010). Schum-
peter meeting keynes: A policy-friendly model of en-
dogenous growth and business cycles. Journal of Eco-
nomic Dynamics and Control, 34(9):1748–1767.
Duffy, J. (2006). Agent-based models and human subject
experiments. In Tesfatsion, L. and Judd, K. L., editors,
Handbook of Computational Economics, volume 2 of
Handbook of Computational Economics, chapter 19,
pages 949–1011. Elsevier.
Duffy, J. (2008). experimental macroeconomics. In
Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E., editors, The New Pal-
grave Dictionary of Economics, volume 3. Palgrave
Macmillan, Basingstoke, second edition.
Epstein, J. M. (2007). Agent-based computational mod-
els and generative social science. In Generative So-
cial Science Studies in Agent-Based Computational
Modeling, Introductory Chapters. Princeton Univer-
sity Press.
Fagiolo, G., Birchenhall, C., and Windrum, P. (2007a). Em-
pirical Validation in Agent-based Models: Introduc-
tion to the Special Issue. Computational Economics,
30(3):189–194.
Fagiolo, G., Moneta, A., and Windrum, P. (2007b). A
critical guide to empirical validation of agent-based
models in economics: Methodologies, procedures,
and open problems. Computational Economics,
30(3):195–226.
Giulioni, G., Bucciarelli, E., Silvestri, M., and D’Orazio,
P. (2013). Agent-based computational economics and
experimental economics: a bridge to progress macroe-
conomics. manuscript submitted.
Gode, D. and Sunder, S. (1991). Allocative efficiency of
markets with zero intelligence (z1) traders: Market
as a partial substitute for individual rationality. Gsia
working papers, Carnegie Mellon University, Tepper
School of Business.
Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system
for economic experiments. Forschung und wis-
senschaftliches rechnen 2003, GWDG Bericht.
Hansen, L. P. and Heckman, J. J. (1996). The empirical
foundations of calibration. Journal of Economic Per-
spectives, 10(1):87–104.
Harrison, G. W., Harstad, R. M., and Rutstrm, E. E. (1995).
Experimental methods and elicitation of values. Dis-
cussion paper serie b, University of Bonn, Germany.
ICAART2014-DoctoralConsortium
20
Hey, J. D. and Dardanoni, V. (1987). Optimal consump-
tion under uncertainty: An experimental investigation.
Economic Journal, 98(390):105–16.
Holland, J. H. and Miller, J. H. (1991). Artificial adaptive
agents in economic theory. The American Economic
Review, 81:365–370.
Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psy-
chology for behavioral economics. American Eco-
nomic Review, 93(5):1449–1475.
Kao, S. Y. F. and Velupillai, K. V. (2011). Behavioural eco-
nomics: Classical and modern. Technical report.
Kinsella, S., Greiff, M., and Nell, E. J. (2011). Income
distribution in a stock-flow consistent model with ed-
ucation and technological change. Eastern Economic
Journal, 37(1):134–149.
Kirman, A. P. (1992). Whom or What Does The Repre-
sentative Individual Represent. Journal of Economic
Perspective, 6:117–36.
LeBaron, B. (2000). Agent-based computational nance:
Suggested readings and early research. Journal of
Economic Dynamics and Control, 24(5-7):679–702.
LeBaron, B. and Tesfatsion, L. (2008). Modeling macroe-
conomies as open-ended dynamic systems of interact-
ing agents. American Economic Review, 98(2):246–
50.
Lucas, R. E. (1986). Adaptive behavior and economic the-
ory. Journal of Business, 59:S401–S426.
Minsky, H. P. (1970). Financial instability revisited: the
economics of disaster. Board of Governors of the Fed-
eral Reserve System, Washington.
Minsky, H. P. (1974). The modeling of financial instabil-
ity: an introduction. In Modelling and Simulation.
Proceedings of the 5th Annual Pittsburg Conference,
pages 267–272.
Minsky, H. P. (1992). The Financial Instability Hypothe-
sis. Working Paper 74, The Jerome Levy Economics
Institute of Bard College.
Raberto, M., Teglio, A., and Cincotti, S. (2012). Debt,
deleveraging and business cycles: An agent-based
perspective. Economics - The Open-Access, Open-
Assessment E-Journal, 6(27):1–49.
Samuelson, L. (2005). Economic theory and experi-
mental economics. Journal of Economic Literature,
43(1):65–107.
Seppecher, P. (2012). Flexibility of wages and macroe-
conomic instability in an agent-based computational
model with endogenous money. Macroeconomic Dy-
namics, 16(S2):284–297.
Simon, H. A. (1959). Theories of Decision-Making in Eco-
nomics and Behavioral Science. The American Eco-
nomic Review, 49(3):253–283.
Smith, V. L. (1982). Microeconomic Systems as an Ex-
perimental Science. American Economic Review,
72(5):923–55.
Smith, V. L. (2002). Method in Experiment: Rhetoric and
Reality. Experimental Economics, 5:91–110.
Smith, V. L., Suchanek, G. L., and Williams, A. W.
(1988). Bubbles, crashes, and endogenous expecta-
tions in experimental spot asset markets. Economet-
rica, 56(5):1119–51.
Stachurski, J. (2009). Economic Dynamics. Theory and
Computation. MIT Press.
Tesfatsion, L. (2003). Agent-based computational eco-
nomics: Modeling economies as complex adaptive
systems. Information Sciences, 149:263–269.
Velupillai, K. V. (2011). Towards an algorithmic revolu-
tion in economic theory. Journal of Economic Sur-
veys, 25(3):401–430.
Waltman, L., Eck, N., Dekker, R., and Kaymak, U. (2011).
Economic modeling using evolutionary algorithms:
the effect of a binary encoding of strategies. Journal
of Evolutionary Economics, 21(5):737–756.
Households'BehaviorsandSystemicFinancialInstability-ExperimentalInsightsandAgent-basedSimulationsfor
MacroeconomicPolicyAnalyses
21