demonstrated that it suppressed the tendency of all
the wealth to go to a single agent, resulting in a
classical distribution, and exhibiting some similar-
ity with empirical forms for wealth distributions due
to Pareto (Pareto, 1965) and Gibrat (Gibrat, 1931).
In later work, however, they demonstrated that the
extreme tail of this distribution decays as a gaus-
sian (Boghosian et al., 2016).
The phenomenon of wealth condensation was
first described by Bouchard and M´ezard in 2000,
who noted the accumulation of macroscopic levels of
weath by a single agent in a simple model of trading
and redistribution (Bouchaud and M´ezard, 2000). In
2007, Moukarzel et al. investigated wealth-attained
advantage (WAA) in the YSM by adding a fixed bias
to the probability of winning in any transaction, de-
pendent only on the sign of the wealth differential.
He observed a first-order phase transition to a wealth-
condensed state of absolute oligarchy, in which a sin-
gle agent held all the wealth (Moukarzel et al., 2007).
More recently, Boghosian et al. (Boghosian et al.,
2016) introduced a new model for WAA in the YSM,
with bias favoring the wealthier agent proportional to
the wealth differential between the two agents, thus
approaching zero continuously for transactions be-
tween agents of equal wealth. This model exhibits a
second-order phase transition to a state of coexistence
between an oligarch and a classical distribution of
non-oligarchs. In that work it was also demonstrated
that the above-mentioned gaussian tail was present
both below and above criticality, but degenerated to
exponential decay precisely at criticality.
While it is perhaps unsurprising that WAA pro-
motes the condensation of wealth, the above obser-
vation demonstrates that the way it is introduced
can have macroscopic consequences. In a first-order
phase transition, order parameters, such as the Gini
coefficient or the fraction of wealth held by the
wealthiest agent in this case, are discontinuous func-
tions of the control parameters. In a second-order
phase transition, they exhibit only slope discontinu-
ities. It seems, therefore, that the continuity or dis-
continuity of the bias in the microscopic model is di-
rectly reflected in the continuity or discontinuity of
the macroscopic order parameter.
To be specific, if the coefficient τ
∞
measures the
level of redistribution for the wealthiest agents, and ζ
measures the level of WAA (in a fashion made pre-
cise in (Boghosian et al., 2016)), then criticality was
shown to occur at ζ = τ
∞
, and coexistence for ζ > τ
∞
.
The fraction of wealth held by the oligarch in the con-
tinuum limit was shown to be
c
∞
=
0 if ζ ≤ τ
∞
1−
τ
∞
ζ
if ζ > τ
∞
(1)
Note that this is a continuous function, with a discon-
tinuous first derivative at the critical point ζ = τ
∞
, re-
flective of a second-order phase transition.
Note that all of the above-described observations
were made for the steady state situation. In this pa-
per we quantify the time dependence of the formation
of partial oligarchy in the model (Boghosian et al.,
2016). We derive a PDE, valid in the coexistence
regime ζ > τ
∞
, governing the distribution of wealth
p(w,t) amongst the non-oligarchs, coupled with an
ODE for the fraction of wealth held by the oligarch,
c(t). The latter is the logistic equation
c
′
(t) = c(t)[−τ
∞
+ ζ(1−c(t))], (2)
whose long-time limit c
∞
:= lim
t→∞
c(t) is consistent
with Eq. (1) for ζ > τ
∞
.
In Section 2 we describe the YSM, and the deriva-
tion of the FP equation describing its behavior. In
particular, we review the assumptions and methodol-
ogy of the Kramers-Moyal derivation of the FP equa-
tion from a stochastic process, because these assump-
tions are violated by the singular distributional solu-
tions that we shall be studying.
In Section 3 we provide a mathematical descrip-
tion for oligarchy as the presence of a singular dis-
tribution Ξ, correct the Kramers-Moyal derivation of
the FP equation, and present the logistic ODE that de-
scribes the wealth of the oligarch. For reasons dis-
cussed in the conclusions, this decouples from the
PDE governing the distribution of non-oligarchs.
2 THE YARD SALE MODEL
In this section we will introduce notation, discuss
the interaction between agents in the modified YSM,
and review the assumptions and methodology of the
Kramers-Moyal derivation of the FP equation from a
stochastic process. While this section follows that of
(Boghosian et al., 2016) closely, this review is neces-
sary because we shall require a weak form of the FP
equation in order to accommodate distributional solu-
tions in what follows.
A continuous distribution of wealth can be de-
scribed by the agent density function (ADF), P(w,t),
defined such that the number of agents with wealth
w ∈ [a,b] at time t is given by
R
b
a
P(w,t)dw. The ze-
roth and first moments of the ADF correspond to the
total number of agents and wealth,
N
P
:=
Z
∞
0
dw P(w,t),
W
P
:=
Z
∞
0
dw P(w,t)w.