Searching for Effective and Efficient Way of Knowledge Transfer within
an Organization
Agnieszka Kowalska-Stycze
´
n
1
, Krzysztof Malarz
2
and Kamil Paradowski
2
1
Silesian University of Technology, Faculty of Organization and Management,
ul. Roosevelta 26/28, PL-41800 Zabrze, Poland
2
AGH University of Science and Technology, Faculty of Physics and Applied Computer Science,
al. Mickiewicza 30, PL-30059 Krakow, Poland
Keywords:
Knowledge Transfer, Distributed Leadership, Complex Systems, Organisations as Complex Systems, Cellular
Automata.
Abstract:
In this paper three models of knowledge transfer in organization are considered. In the first model (A) the
transfer of chunks of knowledge among agents is possible only when the sender has exactly one more chunks
of knowledge than recipient. This is not dissimilar with bounded confidence model of opinion dynamics. In
the second model (B) the knowledge transfer take place when sender is “smarter” than recipient. Finally, in the
third scenario (model C) we allow for knowledge transfer also when sender posses the same or greater number
of chunks of knowledge as recipient. The simulation bases on cellular automata technique. The organization
members occupy nodes of square lattice and they interact only with their nearest neighbors. With computer
simulations we show, that the efficiency and the effectiveness of knowledge transfer i) for model C is better
than for model B ii) and it is worse for model A than for model B.
1 INTRODUCTION
Numerous studies show a relationship between social
interaction and knowledge transfer effectiveness and
organization performance. For example, Chen and
Huang (Chen and Huang, 2007) studied the impact
of organizational climate and organizational structure
for knowledge management from the perspective of
social interaction. The authors of Ref. (Chen and
Huang, 2007) emphasize that the competitiveness of
companies depends not only on knowledge creation,
but mainly from the knowledge diffusion and applica-
tion of knowledge in the organization. They also point
out that, when the organizational structure is less for-
mal, social interaction is more favorable for the trans-
fer and improves the process of knowledge manage-
ment. It was observed also that friendship networks
significantly support the transfer of knowledge, be-
cause in such situation i) the enhanced cooperation,
ii) eased competition iii) and better exchange of in-
formation take place (Ingram and Roberts, 2000).
The influence of the structure of a network of
informal contacts on knowledge transfer was also
studied by the Reagans and McEvily (Reagans and
McEvily, 2003). The study was conducted at R & D
sector, which has a very horizontal organizational
structure, without a formal hierarchy and which em-
ploys mostly scientists and engineers. The authors of
Ref. (Reagans and McEvily, 2003) analyzed, among
others, such factors as: i) the ease of knowledge trans-
fer from the source to the recipient, ii) codifiabil-
ity (ease of availability of knowledge for others), iii)
the strength of ties (the intensity of the connections
in terms of the emotional closeness, iv) and the fre-
quency of communication). Their findings indicate
that i) both social cohesion and long range of interac-
tions facilitate the transfer of knowledge and ii) strong
ties should be used for the transfer of tacit knowledge.
All these works show the importance of social inter-
action, especially informal contacts in the process of
knowledge transfer. Moreover, Reagan and McEvily
(Reagans and McEvily, 2003) demonstrated, that both
strong ties and a dense network of contacts facilitate
knowledge transfer. Such an approach is an indication
to the simulation research and bottom-up approach,
in which relationships at the local level generate the
phenomenon on a global level (i.e. at the level of the
whole organization). Therefore we use the technique
of cellular automata (CA) to model the knowledge
transfer basing on close relationships between mem-
bers of the organization. In our research we focus
on the transfer of knowledge within the organization,
Kowalska-Stycze
´
n, A., Malarz, K. and Paradowski, K.
Searching for Effective and Efficient Way of Knowledge Transfer within an Organization.
DOI: 10.5220/0006546701510158
In Proceedings of the 10th International Conference on Agents and Artificial Intelligence (ICAART 2018) - Volume 1, pages 151-158
ISBN: 978-989-758-275-2
Copyright © 2018 by SCITEPRESS – Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
151
because, as postulated by Watson and Hewett (Wat-
son and Hewett, 2006), acquiring the knowledge con-
tained within the organization is the key i) to building
a competitive advantage and ii) to improve business
performance. New knowledge is created when people
communicate and share their knowledge, assimilate it
and apply it (Wah, 1999). As Davenport and Prusak
add, knowledge exists in humans and is an integral
part of human complexity and unpredictability (Dav-
enport and Prusak, 2000).
As pointed out by P
´
erez-Nordtvedt et al. (P
´
erez-
Nordtvedt et al., 2008), a complete picture of knowl-
edge transfer yield two dimensions of knowledge
transfer: the effectiveness and the efficiency. There-
fore, we study different ways of transfer knowledge
and we are looking for the most efficient and effective
way of transferring knowledge in the organization. It
should be noted that the effectiveness is understood
as the level of adoption of knowledge by the entity
receiving (Jensen and Szulanski, 2007), and the effi-
ciency is defined as the speed with which the recipi-
ent acquires new knowledge (P
´
erez-Nordtvedt et al.,
2008).
We use agent-base modelling. Such a simula-
tion approach for the study of knowledge transfer was
used for example by (Morone and Taylor, 2004; Xuan
et al., 2011; Hirshman et al., 2011; Giacchi et al.,
2016). These studies concerned mainly the impact of
the network properties on the transfer of knowledge
within the network of organization members. Our
goal is to study how knowledge is transferred in the
organization. Based on empirical results (Boone and
Ganeshan, 2008; Alipour et al., 2011; Reagans and
McEvily, 2003) and models of (Morone and Taylor,
2004), Hirshman et al. (Hirshman et al., 2011) we
propose three versions of the knowledge transfer CA
model to examine what way of knowledge transfer in
an organization is more efficient and effective. We
hope the answer to this question will provide practi-
cal guidance for managers to support the transfer of
knowledge in the organization.
In the proposed CA model the lattice fully popu-
lated by agents is used and the von Neumann neigh-
bourhood of four neighbours (as in the model of (Mo-
rone and Taylor, 2004)). This assumption reflects a
dense network of social interaction and strong ties
among agents. This is consistent with the research
of (Reagans and McEvily, 2003) and (Hirshman et al.,
2011), who point out, that the number of strong ties is
on average less than six.
The starting point for our research is recently pro-
posed a CA model (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al., 2017), in
which the transfer of knowledge between agents (the
receiver and sender) is blocked if a distance of their
knowledge (measured by the difference in the number
of chunks of knowledge) is larger than one. Such ap-
proach is consistent with Deffuant et al. model (Def-
fuant et al., 2000) of opinion dynamics where opin-
ion exchange among agents is possible only when
sender and recipient have similar opinions (Hegsel-
mann and Krause, 2002; Malarz, 2006; Kułakowski,
2009; Malarz et al., 2011; Malarz and Kułakowski,
2014). In addition, we propose a model in which
the knowledge transfer is possible if sender has more
chunks of knowledge than recipient and model when
knowledge exchange takes place among agents with
the same or greater numbers of chunks of knowledge:
We assume that the transferred knowledge consists of
certain chunks of knowledge. This concept was in-
spired by model of (Hirshman et al., 2011), where the
transferred knowledge consisted of certain facts (ele-
ments, pieces of knowledge) and studies of (Reagans
and McEvily, 2003), who point out that knowledge in
the firm is into areas (pieces) of expertise.
2 MODEL
In Ref. (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al., 2017) a CA to sim-
ulate the knowledge transfer within an organization
was defined. To describe a CA one should define i)
a d-dimensional network, ii) the set of states of net-
work nodes iii) and the rule defining the system dy-
namics. The above mentioned rule defines state of
node in discrete time t + 1 basing on this node and
its neighborhood state in time t. Here we assume
a two-dimensional square lattice with von Neumann
neighborhood, i.e. node (agent) at discrete coordinate
(x, y) N × N and 1 x, y L has only four near-
est neighbors at (x
0
, y
0
) {(x 1, y),(x + 1, y), (x, y
1), (x, y + 1)}. The set of states describes chunks of
knowledge possessed by the agent. Namely, the vec-
tor variable
C(x, y,t) = [c
1
(x, y,t), c
2
(x, y,t), ··· , c
K
(x, y,t)]
indicates if agent at time t and at the coordination
(x, y) posses k-th chunk of knowledge [c
k
(x, y,t) = 1]
or not [c
k
(x, y,t) = 0] among K chunks of knowledge
desired by organization for their members. Initially
(at t = 0), each agent has each chunk of knowledge
with probability p. Every time step t agent at (x, y)
may inherit single chunk of knowledge from one of
its randomly selected neighbor.
2.1 Model A
For model proposed in Ref. (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al.,
2017) the transfer of chunks of knowledge among
ICAART 2018 - 10th International Conference on Agents and Artificial Intelligence
152
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(a) model A: p = 0.2
.5
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(c) model B: p = 0.2
.5
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 5 10 15 20 25 30
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(e) model C: p = 0.2
.5
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 2 4 6 8 10
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(b) model A: p = 0.5
.5
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 2 4 6 8 10
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(d) model B: p = 0.5
.5
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 2 4 6 8 10
0
1
2
3
4
n(k)[%]
t
k =
(f) model C: p = 0.5
Figure 1: The time evolution of the fraction n(k) of agents having k chunks of knowledge for L = 20, K = 4 and various
initial concentration p of chunks of knowledge among agents. The results are averaged over M = 10
4
independent simulations.
(a)-(b) model A, (c)-(d) model B, (e)-(f) model C.
agents is possible only when the sender has exactly
one more chunks of knowledge than recipient:
c
k
(x, y,t + 1) = 1 c
k
(x, y,t) = 0
and c
k
(x
0
, y
0
,t) = 1 and ν(x
0
, y
0
,t) = ν(x, y,t)+1,
(1)
where ν(x, y, t) and ν(x
0
, y
0
,t) are numbers of chunks
of knowledge at time t for receiver and sender of
knowledge, respectively.
2.2 Model B
As we mentioned in the Introduction, here we would
like to omit the restriction of knowledge transfer
only from senders having exactly one more chunk of
knowledge than recipient. Namely, we allow for send-
ing chunk of knowledge from neighbors at (x
0
, y
0
) to
recipient at (x,y) if sender has more chunks of knowl-
edge than recipient:
c
k
(x, y,t + 1) = 1 c
k
(x, y,t) = 0
and c
k
(x
0
, y
0
,t) = 1 and ν(x
0
, y
0
,t) > ν(x, y, t). (2)
2.3 Model C
Finally, we modify the rule described in Sec. 2.2 in
order to allowing for transfer of chunks of knowledge
among agents with the same or grater numbers of
chunks of knowledge:
c
k
(x, y,t + 1) = 1 c
k
(x, y,t) = 0
and c
k
(x
0
, y
0
,t) = 1 and ν(x
0
, y
0
,t) ν(x, y, t). (3)
In further part of this paper we will refer to
these three models as model A [Eq. (1)], model B
[Eq. (2)] and model C [Eq. (3)], respectively. Java
applet presenting system evolution is available at
http://www.zis.agh.edu.pl/knowledge transfer/.
3 THE DESIGN OF
EXPERIMENTS
Experiments that have been conducted were designed
to investigate which of the three models gives the
most effective and efficient transfer of knowledge.
Similarly to the work (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al.,
2017), the following independent variables were cho-
sen in the designed experiments: i) maximal number
of chunks of knowledge K ii) and initial concentration
of chunks of knowledge p.
Our goal is to seek the most efficient and the
most effective way to transfer knowledge. In view
of the above, we define the corresponding variables
describing these two parameters of knowledge trans-
fer. Firstly, as the dependent variable describing an
effectiveness of knowledge transfer the following pa-
rameters were adopted:
the fraction n(k) of agents having k chunks of
knowledge,
the fraction n(K) of agents having all chunks of
knowledge,
the fraction f (k) of agents having k-th chunk of
knowledge c
k
,
Searching for Effective and Efficient Way of Knowledge Transfer within an Organization
153
the coverage h f i of any chunks of knowledge c
k
in
agents knowledge, i.e. the fraction of knowledge
chunks held by typical member of the organiza-
tion.
Secondly, as the dependent variable describing an ef-
ficiency of knowledge transfer, the time τ necessary
for reaching a stationary state was adopted.
4 RESULTS
In order to compare efficiency of the knowledge trans-
fer among newly proposed (Sec. 2.2 and 2.3) and
previously discussed (Sec. 2.1) models we have re-
produced some results presented in Ref. (Kowalska-
Stycze
´
n et al., 2017) but for ten times better statistic,
i.e. for M = 10
4
, where M is the number of indepen-
dent simulations used for averaging procedure. This
number of independent simulations is also applied for
simulations based on models B and C.
4.1 Time Evolution of the Fraction of
Agents Having k Chunks of
Knowledge
In Fig. 1 the time evolution of the fraction n(k) of
agents having k chunks of knowledge for L = 20,
K = 4 and p = 0.2, 0.5 and for various models are
presented. The fraction n(k) is formally defined as
n(k)
M
r=1
N
r
(k)
ML
2
, (4)
where N
r
(k) stands for the number of agents having
exactly k chunks of knowledge in r-th simulation, M
is the number of independent simulations and L is lin-
ear size of the system. For low initial concentration
of chunks of knowledge among agents (p = 0.2) the
differences between results of model A and model B
seems to be negligible, except that time τ of reach-
ing the stationary state is a little bit shorter for model
B. The same apply for p = 0.5. Here however, addi-
tionally we observe that fraction of agents possessing
less than K chunks of knowledge vanishes for long
enough simulation times. Simultaneously, the frac-
tion of agents with all chunks of knowledge saturates
at n(K) = 1 while n(K) < 1 for simulations based
on model A. These effects are enhanced when model
C is applied. Moreover, for model C the fraction
of agents with all chunks of knowledge increases to
n(K) = 1 even for low initial level (p = 0.2) of chunks
of knowledge among agents.
The effectiveness of the knowledge transfer mea-
sured by n(k) depends on p and on the method of
knowledge transfer (models A, B, C) as presented in
Fig. 1. The greater initial concentration p of chunks
of knowledge the higher the percentage n(k) of agents
having k chunks of knowledge, as can be seen by
comparing upper [Fig. 1(a, c, e), p = 0.2] and lower
[Fig. 1(b, d, f), p = 0.5] panels of Fig. 1. Furthermore,
comparing the results for model A, B and C one can
see that the knowledge transfer is most effective in the
case of the model C while it is quite similar in the case
of models A and B.
Now let us look at the efficiency of knowledge
transfer. In Fig. 1 the efficiency can be understood
as the time (number of simulation steps) required to
obtain the maximum fraction n(k) of agents having k
chunks of knowledge. In the case of the model C, the
time of the transfer of knowledge is much shorter than
for models A and B.
4.2 Time Evolution of the Fraction of
Agents Having All Chunks of
Knowledge
In Fig. 2 the time evolution of the fraction n(K) of
agents having total knowledge—i.e. possessing all K
chunks of knowledge (c
1
, c
2
, · · · , c
K
) = (1, 1, · · · , 1) is
presented. In Fig. 2(a) the data for model A are re-
produced. The data obtained for model B [Fig. 2(b)]
exhibit again shorter times of reaching the saturation
of curves n(K) with simulation steps t vs. the same
data for model A. Moreover, for model B and for ini-
tial concentrations of chunks of knowledge p > 0.3
the curves n(K) saturates at n(K) = 1 while in model
A n(K) < 1 independently on p. Finally, for model
C, these effects are strongly enhanced and for all
checked values of initial concentration of chunks of
knowledge p only several simulations steps are re-
quired to reach n(K) = 1.
As it was mentioned earlier, n(K) is also a variable
describing the effectiveness of knowledge transfer. As
can be seen in Fig. 2, the effectiveness of knowledge
transfer is greater for model A than B, but definitely
the best results gives model C. In this case, even small
values of initial fraction p cause that all the organiza-
tion members have all K required chunks of knowl-
edge.
4.3 Time Necessary for Reaching the
Stationary State
In Fig. 3 times τ necessary for reaching the stationary
state as dependent on initial concentration of chunks
of knowledge p for L = 20 and K = 4, 8 and vari-
ous models are presented. In Fig. 3(a) the results pre-
ICAART 2018 - 10th International Conference on Agents and Artificial Intelligence
154
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
(a) model A
p =
t
n(K) [%]
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
(b) model B
p =
t
n(K) [%]
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
(c) model C
p =
t
n(K) [%]
Figure 2: The time evolution of the fraction n(K) of agents
having total knowledge—i.e. possessing all K chunks of
knowledge (c
1
, c
2
, · ·· , c
K
) = (1, 1, ·· · , 1) for L = 20 and
K = 4. The values of n(K) are averaged over M = 10
4
in-
dependent simulations.
sented in Ref. (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al., 2017) are re-
produced. The heuristic low degree polynomial fit has
been added for eyes guidance as well. For model B—
when agents may receive chunks of knowledge from
“smarter” agents—we observe shorter times τ in re-
spect to results of model A for both checked values
of K. However, the characteristic of the fit shapes
are roughly the same for models A and B. This sit-
uation changes qualitatively and quantitatively when
model C is applied—the obtained values of τ are
twice smaller when comparing with results for model
A and the fit shape is different than for models A and
B.
The number of simulation steps τ to obtain the
steady state, expresses the efficiency of knowledge
transfer. As can be seen in Fig. 3, the time of the
transfer of knowledge is shorter in the case of model B
than A, but definitely it is shortest for the model C. In
the latter case, the time τ decreases with increasing p.
The transfer of knowledge chunks among agents with
the same or greater numbers of chunks of knowledge
therefore gives the best results.
4.4 The Average Coverage of Chunks of
Knowledge in Whole Organization
In Fig. 4 the average coverage of chunks of knowl-
edge
h f i = K
1
K
k=1
f (k)
of agents having any chunk of knowledge c
k
for L =
20 and long simulations time t and various val-
ues of K (K = 2, 3, 4, 8, 16) as dependent on initial
concentration of chunks of knowledge p is presented.
The fraction f (k) is formally defined as
f (k)
M
r=1
F
r
(k)
ML
2
, (5)
where F
r
(k) is the number of agents having k-th chunk
of knowledge [i.e. with c
k
(x, y,t ) = 1] in r-th
simulation.
In this experiment, we can look at the effective-
ness of knowledge transfer more globally, i.e. in the
whole system (the whole organization). The more
chunks of knowledge (K) is required in the organi-
zation, the greater must be the initial concentration of
knowledge in the organization (p) to allow almost all
agents acquire the required knowledge [see Fig. 4].
Moreover, comparing the three models A, B and C—
and basing on results presented in Fig. 4—the trans-
fer of knowledge is more effective for model B than
A. A lower values of initial concentration of chunks
of knowledge p are required to ensure the global sat-
uration of skills in organization (h f i = 1) when com-
paring models B and A [cf. Fig. 4(d) and Fig. 4(b)].
For model B these values increse with the number of
chunks of knowledge K desired in the organization.
Obviously the best results, as in the previous experi-
ments, are obtained for the situation C [cf. Fig. 4(f)
and Fig. 4(d)].
As it was mentioned in Ref. (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n
et al., 2017), for model A (Sec. 2.1), “the dependence
h f i on p increases to a certain threshold values of p
[. . . ] then it decreases, and it increases again [. . . ]
Searching for Effective and Efficient Way of Knowledge Transfer within an Organization
155
0
5
10
15
20
25
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
4
8
(a) model A
p
τ
K =
0
5
10
15
20
25
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
4
8
(b) model B
p
τ
K =
0
5
10
15
20
25
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
4
8
(c) model C
p
τ
K =
Figure 3: The time τ necessary for reaching the stationary state as dependent on initial concentration of chunks of knowledge
p. The results are averaged over M = 10
4
independent simulations. The error bars are smaller than the symbols. (a) model A,
(b) model B, (c) model C.
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(a) model A
h f i [%]
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(c) model B
h f i [%]
0
20
40
60
80
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(e) model C
h f i [%]
90
92
94
96
98
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(b) model A
h f i [%]
90
92
94
96
98
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(d) model B
h f i [%]
90
92
94
96
98
100
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1
2
3
4
8
16
p
K =
(f) model C
h f i [%]
Figure 4: The average coverage of chunks of knowledge h f i of agents having any chunk of knowledge c
k
for L = 20 and
long simulations time t and various values of K (K = 2, 3, 4, 8, 16) as dependent on initial concentration of chunks of
knowledge p. The values of h f i are averaged over M = 10
4
independent simulations.
We see [. . . ], that for L = 20 and K 7 a drop in
h f i is absent. The surprising effect of decreasing the
effectiveness of the knowledge transfer with increas-
ing the initial concentration p of chunks of knowledge
among agents for K < 7 [cf. Figs. 4(a-b)] was directly
associated with and explained by the assumed rules of
the knowledge transfer described in Ref. (Kowalska-
Stycze
´
n et al., 2017). In particular, for the minimal
set (K = 2) of required chunks of knowledge one may
evaluate the mean-field-like probabilities of finding
pairs of agents allowing for knowledge transfer or
blocking it (Kowalska-Stycze
´
n et al., 2017). The lat-
ter vanishes for model B and for model C, what re-
sults in monotonically non-decreasing h f i vs. p de-
pendencies for model B and model C as presented
in Figs. 4(c-d) and 4(e-f). Moreover, when sending
the chunks of knowledge is not restricted only to the
“smarter” agents (model C), the quantitative differ-
ence on h f i vs. p curves for various values of K
disappears. As we can deduce from Fig. 4(e-f)—
when model C is assumed—the agents are able to ac-
quire all chunks of knowledge desired by the organi-
zation independently on the level K of the knowledge
required in the organization if only initial concen-
tration of chunks of knowledge is sufficiently large.
Moreover, in model C, agents will not acquire all of
K chunks of knowledge only when some chunk of
knowledge will not be available initially in the orga-
nization, i.e. when
k x, y : c
k
(x, y, 0) = 0 and (x, y) N ×N, 1 x, y L.
(6)
The condition (6) is fulfilled with probability
p
= 1
(1 p)
L
2
K
, (7)
which is the probability that at least one column in
random binary matrix with K columns and L
2
rows
will contain only zeros when matrix elements are “1”
with probability p and “0” with probability (1 p).
The dependencies p
(p) for L = 20 and various val-
ues of K are presented in Fig. 5. As we can see, the
ICAART 2018 - 10th International Conference on Agents and Artificial Intelligence
156
probabilities that some chunks of knowledge will be
initially missing in organization with L
2
= 400 mem-
bers are marginal if p > 2%.
Figure 5: The dependencies p
(p) [Eq. (7)] for L = 20 and
various values of K.
5 DISCUSSION AND
CONCLUSION
In this article the transfer of knowledge in an organi-
zation is studied. The goal is to find an effective and
efficient way of communicating knowledge among
members of the organization, i.e. we are searching
for models giving better efficiency and better effec-
tivity of knowledge transfer. Therefore, we have in-
vestigated a CA model to answer the question if dif-
ferences on the microscopic scale between the three
versions of the knowledge transfer model manifest in
differences in the efficiency and speed of knowledge
transfer.
Many studies show the importance of social inter-
action among organizational members in knowledge
exchange (Chen and Huang, 2007; Ibarra, 1993; Tsai,
2002). It should be noted, that these interactions be-
tween organization members are mainly informal and
these interactions are the main source of influence in
organizations (Ibarra, 1993). Therefore, the proposed
models base on informal relations between the orga-
nization members. Moreover, apart from the stock
of knowledge, the efficient knowledge transfer re-
quires the strong disseminative capacity of knowledge
senders and the absorptive capacity of knowledge re-
ceivers (Tang, 2011). The abilities of people i) to
efficiently and effectively communicate, ii) to spread
knowledge in a way that other people can understand
information accurately, iii) and to use knowledge in
practice are very important. The lack of competence,
skills and language efficiency of knowledge senders
makes the transfer of their knowledge to others rather
difficult (Cabrera, 2003). It should be added, that
in this knowledge transfer process, leaders also play
an important role (Girdauskiene and Savaneviciene,
2012). They become informal leaders (distributed
leadership), when leadership is understood as a com-
mon social process resulting from the interaction of
multiple entities (Uhl-Bien, 2006). In this perspec-
tive, the way of leaders interaction with others is more
important than the nature of their leadership roles, re-
sponsibilities or functions (Harris, 2012). In connec-
tion with this, we define the rule of knowledge trans-
fer as a transfer of knowledge from the people who
have more of knowledge chunks (leaders) to people
with less of knowledge chunks (followers).
In this paper we have assumed three situations in
which the sender is eligible to transfer knowledge to
the recipient:
when the sender has exactly one more chunks of
knowledge than recipient (model A),
when the sender has more chunks of knowledge
than recipient (model B),
when the sender has the same or greater number
of chunks of knowledge than recipient (model C).
As we have shown, the differences between model
A and B are almost negligible (are not large), although
the model B gives a better result than model A. In
the model B, we assume that the transfer occurs when
sender has more chunks of knowledge than recipient
(i.e. when the sender generally has a greater knowl-
edge of the recipient). It seems to be better than the
assumptions in the model A, because, it seems more
natural that people with more knowledge (knowledge
leaders) share it with others. The knowledge transfer
is most effective in the model C. In this situation, the
senders are also people who have the same number of
chunks knowledge as the recipient (i.e., they may be
at a similar level of knowledge).
The simulations, for all three models, show a sig-
nificant role of initial concentration of knowledge
chunks in the transfer process. Organizations should
therefore carry out training courses for their employ-
ees in order to increase the initial knowledge in the
organization. However, as it was shown earlier, the
most important is the way to knowledge transfer.
The best results are obtained when the transfer of
knowledge is possible when the recipient have the
same or lower level of knowledge from the broad-
casters (model C), because the knowledge transfer oc-
curs more frequently. Therefore, in case of sponta-
neous knowledge transfer, managers should develop
and support informal contacts between employees to
reduce the social distance between them.
Searching for Effective and Efficient Way of Knowledge Transfer within an Organization
157
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
This research was supported by National Sci-
ence Center (NCN) in Poland (grant no. UMO-
2014/15/B/HS4/04433) and partially by Polish Min-
istry of Science and Higher Education.
REFERENCES
Alipour, F., Idris, K., and Karimi, R. (2011). Knowl-
edge creation and transfer: role of learning organiza-
tion. International Journal of Business Administra-
tion, 2(3):61–67.
Boone, T. and Ganeshan, R. (2008). Knowledge acqui-
sition and transfer among engineers: Effects of net-
work structure. Managerial and Decision Economics,
29(5):459–468.
Cabrera, E. (2003). Social-psychological aspects of
knowledge-sharing in organizations. In Morley, M.,
Cross, C., Flood, P., Gubbins, C., Heraty, N., and
Sheikh, H., editors, Proceedings of 7th Conference on
International Human Resource Management. Intere-
source Group Publishing.
Chen, C. and Huang, J. (2007). How organizational climate
and structure affect knowledge management—the so-
cial interaction perspective. International Journal of
Information Management, 27(2):104–118.
Davenport, T. H. and Prusak, L. (2000). Working knowl-
edge: How organizations manage what they know.
Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.
Deffuant, G., Neau, D., Amblard, F., and Weisbuch, G.
(2000). Mixing beliefs among interacting agents. Ad-
vances in Complex Systems, 3(1-4):87.
Giacchi, E., La Corte, A., and Di Pietro, E. (2016). A dy-
namic and context-aware model of knowledge trans-
fer and learning using a decision making perspective.
In Mu
˜
noz, V. M., Gusikhin, O., and Chang, V., edi-
tors, Proceedings of the 1st International Conference
on Complex Information Systems, pages 66–73. Sci-
ence and Technology Publications.
Girdauskiene, L. and Savaneviciene, A. (2012). Leadership
role implementing knowledge transfer in creative or-
ganization: how does it work? Procedia—Social and
Behavioral Sciences, 41:15–22.
Harris, A. (2012). Distributed leadership: implications for
the role of the principal. Journal of Management De-
velopment, 31(1):7–17.
Hegselmann, R. and Krause, U. (2002). Opinion dynamics
and bounded confidence: models, analysis and simu-
lation. JASSS—the Journal of Artificial Societies and
Social Simulation, 5(3):2.
Hirshman, B. R., Charles, J. S., and M., C. K. (2011). Leav-
ing us in tiers: can homophily be used to generate tier-
ing effects? Computational and Mathematical Orga-
nization Theory, 17:318–343.
Ibarra, H. (1993). Network centrality, power, and innova-
tion involvement: Determinants of technical and ad-
ministrative roles. Academy of Management Journal,
36(3):471–501.
Ingram, P. and Roberts, P. (2000). Friendships among com-
petitors in the sydney hotel industry. American Jour-
nal of Sociology, 106(2):387–423.
Jensen, R. J. and Szulanski, G. (2007). Template use and
the effectiveness of knowledge transfer. Management
Science, 53(11):1716–173.
Kowalska-Stycze
´
n, A., Malarz, K., and Paradowski, K.
(2017). Model of knowledge transfer within an or-
ganization.
Kułakowski, K. (2009). Opinion polarization in the receip-
tacceptsample model. Physica A: Statistical Mechan-
ics and its Applications, 388(4):469–476.
Malarz, K. (2006). Truth seekers in opinion dynamics
models. International Journal of Modern Physics C,
17(10):1521–1524.
Malarz, K., Gronek, P., and Kułakowski, K. (2011). Zaller–
Deffuant model of mass opinion. JASSS—the Journal
of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 14(1):2.
Malarz, K. and Kułakowski, K. (2014). Mental ability and
common sense in an artificial society. Europhysics
News, 45(4):21–23.
Morone, P. and Taylor, R. (2004). Knowledge diffusion dy-
namics and network properties of face-to-face interac-
tions. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14(3):327–
351.
P
´
erez-Nordtvedt, L., Kedia, B. L., Datta, D. K., and
Rasheed, A. A. (2008). Effectiveness and efficiency of
cross-border knowledge transfer: an empirical exam-
ination. Journal of Management Studies, 45(4):714–
744.
Reagans, R. and McEvily, B. (2003). Network structure
and knowledge transfer: The effects of cohesion and
range. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(2):240–
267.
Tang, F. (2011). Knowledge transfer in intra-organization
networks. Systems Research and Behavioral Science,
28(3):270–282.
Tsai, W. (2002). Social structure of ‘coopetition’ within
a multiunit organization: Coordination, competition,
and intra-organizational knowledge sharing. Organi-
zation Science, 13(2):179–190.
Uhl-Bien, M. (2006). Relational leadership theory: Explor-
ing the social processes of leadership and organizing.
Leadership Quarterly, 17(6):654–676.
Wah, L. (1999). Behind the buzz. Management Review,
88(4):17–26.
Watson, S. and Hewett, K. (2006). A multi-theoretical
model of knowledge transfer in organizations: De-
terminants of knowledge contribution and knowledge
reuse. Journal of Management Studies, 43(2):141–
173.
Xuan, Z., Xia, H., and Du, Y. (2011). Adjustment of
knowledge-connection structure affects the perfor-
mance of knowledge transfer. Expert Systems with
Applications, 38(12):14935–14944.
ICAART 2018 - 10th International Conference on Agents and Artificial Intelligence
158