Coal Business and Local Political Dynamics
Andi Tenri Sompa
Ilmu Pemerintahan FISIP Unversitas Lambung Mangkurat, Banjarmasin
Keywords: coal, decentralisation, local politics, mining
Abstract: Coal is not just economic goods, but also political "stuff". As economic goods, coal is one form of natural
wealth of Indonesia which became the object of business because it has a high selling value. In a number of
areas in Kalimantan and Sumatra, investment activities are based on natural resources, in general coal. This
study attempts to answer three questions. Firstly, is the regional authority in mining business licensing
consistent in formal procedures or are there also informal procedures? Secondly, whose interests are
primary in coal-based investment activities in Tanah Bumbu? Thirdly, how is the involvement of coal mine
operators in the political process, especially the 2005 and 2010 elections in Tanah Bumbu District following
the implications in the context of local power?
1 INTRODUCTION
As an economic good, coal has its own political
values and implications. Business and investment in
coal are related to political practices, especially at
the local political level (As'ad, 2015). Beginning
with permission from clearance for exploration and
exploitation to marketing results, there are the
interests of local political elites (and bureaucratic
officials) which cannot be separated in coal business
and investment. In various districts/municipalities in
South Kalimantan, for example, where there is a
booming coal business, it is clear that there is a
strong political dimension in it (As'ad, 2015).
The interests of the local political elite (and
related bureaucracy officials) in the coal business are
in line with the level and scope of regional authority
in natural resource management (Dinas
Pertambangan dan Energi Kalsel, 2011). In UU No.
4 of 2009 on Mineral and Coal Mining, regional
(provincial and district/city) positions in natural
resource management (minerals and coal) are
important and strategic, ranging from local
regulation, business licenses, guidance, settlement
conflicts, inventories, research, exploration,
geological information management, resource
potential information, development and
empowerment of local communities, delivery of
inventory information, guidance, supervision of
post-mining land reclamation, and others (Dinas
Pertambangan dan Energi Kalsel, 2011).
The wide scope of authority allows for regions
(local political elites and related bureaucratic
officials) to do many things both for the benefit of
regional progress and other interests. For potential
areas of natural resources, such as Tanah Bumbu
District, South Kalimantan, local governments are
eager to encourage investment activities in the coal
mining sector as a substantial natural resource in the
district. In Tanah Bumbu District, most of the
investment activities are based on the coal industry.
Conditions in early 2011, for example, showed that
more than 90% of investment activities were in the
coal sector with the company amounted to about 176
pieces, while in 2007-2008 only around 46 Mining
Business Licenses (IUP) for coal were granted.
Coal-based investment activities are basically
required to drive the economy and earn revenue in
order to build the region and create people's welfare.
But, is this always, in fact, policy? There is an
indication of the exchange of interests between
political elites and businessman concerning
investment activities in the coal sector in Tanah
Bumbu. These indications look from the process of
licensing to marketing results.
In the seasons of the election of regional heads, it
is clear that there is a certain proximity between
political actors (regional head candidates) and coal
mining businessmen. The closeness is certainly not
66
Sompa, A.
Coal Business and Local Political Dynamics.
DOI: 10.5220/0008816800660070
In Proceedings of the 4th International Conference on Contemporary Social and Political Affairs (ICoCSPA 2018), pages 66-70
ISBN: 978-989-758-393-3
Copyright
c
2019 by SCITEPRESS Science and Technology Publications, Lda. All rights reserved
something just plain, but implies a special
relationship which, in turn, has broad implications
(Sung and Richter, 2007).
This study attempts to answer three questions.
Firstly, is the regional authority in mining business
licensing consistent in the formal procedures or are
there also informal procedures? Secondly, whose
interests are primary in coal-based investment
activities in Tanah Bumbu? Thirdly, how does the
involvement of coal mine operators in the political
process, especially the 2005 and 2010 elections in
Tanah Bumbu District, follow the implications in the
context of local power?
This research aims to understand the power
relations that occur between the political elite and
coal mining businessmen in the local political sphere
of Tanah Bumbu Regency. This research is placed
within the local political sphere and touches on
political economy.
2 DECENTRALIZATION AND
LOCAL POLITICS
In political studies, decentralisation refers to the
distribution of power based on territory.
Decentralisation is concerned with the extent to
which power and authority are handed over through
a geographical hierarchy within the state and also
with respect to the institutions and processes that
permit such divisions (Balmas et al., 2014).
Smith mentioned at least 6 (six) promises of
decentralisation in the context of development.
According to Smith, the state mobilises support for
development plans. Popular energy needs to be
utilised for economic tasks or regeneration
(Whitford, 2007). Plans and goals must be delivered
in difficult physical and cultural conditions. Local
institutions can provide local data, interpretations of
local needs, indoctrination (into benefits of health
programs, for example), inputs (such as savings and
direct labour), and community self-help projects.
Profits can be derived from what is believed to be a
willingness to pay locally greater than the central
tax.
Local governments allow the maximum use of
local resources that have efficiency value quite apart
from other benefits, such as political education,
which may be brought to the community. Therefore,
it is very closely related to democratic
decentralisation and development that seeks to
utilise the capacity to help oneself with the aim of
improving the economic and social welfare of the
"community" (Patnaik, 2013).
In the meantime, local politics at its baseline
cannot explain and photograph problems within the
scope of the administration of local government and
legal-formal relationships between government
institutions, but more so than that concerning the
dynamics of politics, social and economic factors in
the local sphere which suggest the occurrence of
seizure interests, intergroup competition, conflict,
behaviour of actors, and others (Boulding and
Gibson, 2009).
3 RATIONAL CHOICE
The rational choice theory, sometimes called the
public choice theory, explains the close relationship
between public choice and public goods (Lehtinen
and Kuorikoski, 2007). This theory focuses on the
individual who makes the choice, the choice and the
behaviour of the maximization that he does. The
individual's decision or choice affects the public,
though the public itself understands that they are not
the select actors (Schotter, 2006).
Buchanan examines how to organise society to
be able to enlarge opportunities freely, both in the
context of the economy (market) and in the political
(state) context. According to Buchanan, the political
system is judged desirable to the extent that it
facilitates voluntary exchange and proportionate
relations between private costs and public provided
(but privately) benefits (Whitford, 2007).
This theory departs from the assumption of
utility maximisation. It is understood that the pillars
of society are individuals, rational actors who
always act to achieve their own interests. Taking
advantage of the concept borrowed from micro-
economic discipline, the theorists of this theory are
going to explain what is often called the micro
foundation of politics (Edlin, Gelman, and Kaplan,
2007).
4 RESEARCH FINDINGS
4.1 Playing on Mine Licensing
Mine clearance does have a clear procedure, but
often the procedure is only a formal way to go. In
practice, the informal procedure is more decisive.
Lobbying is usually done by investors, and it is part
of its informal procedures. Not infrequently,
Coal Business and Local Political Dynamics
67
informal procedures have their own strength in the
issuance of permits to control mining land to
investors. As stated and experienced by Kustono,
there are a number of companies whose licensing
application documents are incomplete but who
suddenly already have land and run mining
activities. Engineering always seems to exist. They
mine firstly take care of the permit then because
there is already a signature or recommendation of
the regent. In Tanah Bumbu, many officials,
including police officials, are involved in the coal
mining business.
4.2 Elite and Mine Businessmen
Interests
On the one hand, of course, the contribution of the
coal mining business in the development of Tanah
Bumbu Regency cannot be denied. On the other
hand, there are many complaints from various
circles where there are less positive implications of
business and the mining industry. The prosperity and
welfare of the people are not improving greatly even
though the exploitation of natural resources (coal
and oresbesi) continues to be done and contributes a
lot to the Original Revenue.
This is basically related to the concession and
impact of the coal mining industry for improving the
welfare of local communities. In reality, more
concessions are given to businessmen. In terms of
business concessions, the authorities will also try to
accommodate the various business concessions of
the businessmen. The Susanto study in South
Kalimantan Province, for example, shows the
granting of concessions from local authorities to
businessmen who can be inventoried in the form of:
[a] awarding of development projects, which can be
done through appointment even without a tender;
[b] granting mining authorisation to businessmen;
[c] provision of border area provisions between
Banjar Regency and Tanah Bumbu Regency; [d]
issuance of appointment letters in procurement and
construction; [e] provision of concessions to the
process of transporting coal mining products; and [f]
compensation for the cost of the Barito river
dredging.
The role of the state or government is also
reduced (simplification) from protecting the interests
of the whole society to just keep the interests of
businessmen. The task is both simple and vulgar.
This is exactly what is imagined in the minimal
market concept. The powers they hold are merely
used to serve the businessmen, and beat other groups
in society who disagree.
According to Sarman, Haji Kalam in the
context of the mining business in Tanah Bumbu
District has emerged as a strongman. But he is a
powerful man who is likely to be created or
deliberately created by someone who is actually
stronger and might be in Jakarta. Thus, Haji Kalam
is a strong man created by a stronger person to
secure his business interests in Tanah Bumbu
District and also in South Kalimantan. That way,
Haji Kalam could be a puppet or an accomplice of
another stronger person.
Presumably, such a reality occurs in Tanah
Bumbu Regency that can be categorised by Studwell
as demonstrating the relationship between money
and power. The money is owned and controlled by
tycoons called godfathers, while power is in the
hands of formal leaders. According to Studwell, the
godfather is a peculiar elite, an economic aristocracy
of outsiders who cooperate half-heartedly with the
local elite. Culturally, the godfathers are chameleons
who tend to be well-educated, cosmopolitan, speak
more than one language and are completely isolated
from the boring attention of people who are
considered to be their relatives.
Under such circumstances it always happens
what Acemoglu and Robinson as extractive political
institutions (extractive political institutions) and
extractive economic institutions (extractive
economic institutions). A power that actually has
roots and traditions in the past, now repeats itself
with the same perpetrator. On a different side
emerge inclusive political institutions and inclusive
economic institutions. Political institutions and
extractive economics are within the framework of
vicious circles, while inclusive political and
economic institutions are placed within the
framework of virtuous circles.
4.3 Coal Businessman and Elections
Every coal miner in Tanah Bumbu Regency,
especially those with a large business, does not want
their business disturbed let alone stagnating and
experiencing congestion. Thus, they deem it
necessary to establish close and friendly relations
with local political leaders. The reason, many things
they can do in the context of business if close and
friendly with political rulers, should be so. Thus,
there is a symbiotic mutualism between the two
forces.
ICoCSPA 2018 - International Conference on Contemporary Social and Political Affairs
68
This happened in the case of elections in several
districts in South Kalimantan in 2005. The results of
the Indonesian Institute of Science study say,
explicitly, in the form of explicit/explicit indeed
there is no alliance between employers and
authorities. Of course, this can be a form of strong
alliance because they have a double position, namely
as a ruler as well as a businessman. With the
establishment of an alliance between rulers and
businessmen, the expectation of businessmen will be
that they will be able to participate in local
government projects listed in the APBD. Some of
the occurrences of alliance can be demonstrated by
several causes, partly because of the electoral
process in which the role of businessmen is very
large in supporting certain candidates.
Businessmen who provide support for the
election process will certainly collect project
promises in the post-election period. Therefore, it
can be argued that the main mode of businessmen in
politics is to influence the policies of local
governments that will side with the interests of the
businessman in gaining access to the implementation
of local government projects.
In order to influence local government policy,
businessmen also formulate "shadow cabinets" and
place their people to occupy certain positions. With
people who have close relationships (with partners)
with employers occupying the cabinet seat area, they
can do "escort projects". In this case, the
businessman escorts the superior project through his
"hands" in the legislature the executive, who is
allied with the employers' partners. Some
businessmen do not engage in direct contact with the
head of the region who are important actors outside
the formal structure of government, or through the
regional secretary.
Large businessmen are usually directly related to
the candidate, while middle-level businessmen and
small businessmen, in addition to dealing with
successful teams are also associated with undercover
or disguised teams. Usually disguised teams come
from families, are younger siblings or children of
businessmen commonly referred to as "ring one", or
because the candidate is an incumbent, then the one
ring is the heads of service, the echelon one, and the
two echelons.
5 CONCLUSION
The regional authority in licensing coal mining, in
addition to making it easier for investors to secure
their business and investment activities, also has its
own implications in the context of local politics. On
the one hand, local governments need investments
and financial resources as a force in mobilising
regional development; on the other hand, mine
businesspeople need land and local government
support to grow businesses and scale businesses.
Business licenses issued by the local government, on
the one hand, provide economic benefits for the
region and increase regional income; on the other
hand, they become "goods" that have a political
meaning of their own. In Tanah Bumbu District, the
coal mining business license becomes a political
business field involving the political elite and related
bureaucratic officials.
Coal mining investment activity in Tanah Bumbu
Regency is quite large and produces a lot of income
for the region but it does not have many implications
for the improvement of people's prosperity. The high
income of the region from mining business results
does not go hand in hand with efforts to improve the
welfare of the community. Physical development
looks more as if it prioritises local government
rather than accelerating community empowerment.
The interests of businessmen as well as the financial
benefits of the political elite and bureaucratic
officials seem more advanced. Thus, investment
activities in the coal sector are more prominent as
the arena of interest and profit for local businessmen
and elites than the interests of development and
regional progress.
Another political dimension of the coal business
in Tanah Bumbu is evident in the political event of
the Regional Head Elections. In the 2005 and 2010
elections, for example, a number of mining
businessmen provided support to certain candidates,
not only moral and mass support but also financial
assistance for the various needs of candidates in the
electoral process. The interests of mining
businessmen in the elections are not limited to the
candidates who support the winning candidate, but
also later business interests of the businessmen still
occur after the candidate has been elected as
regional head. Policies are formulated and enforced
by elected regional heads. Therefore, every
candidate who wins an election is never separated
from the support and involvement of coal mining
businessmen.
The support provided by mining businessmen to
regional head candidates in the pilkada is certainly
not free. They expect a reward, and when elected,
the reward will be given in the form of facilities in
the development of the coal mining business as
required by the mine itself. Thus, the cooperation
and relationship between regional leaders and coal
Coal Business and Local Political Dynamics
69
mine businessmen not only lasts during the political
process (pilkada) but also in later periods; in fact, in
later times, the closeness is far more important than
ever. That is why many of the local leaders' policies
in the coal mining sector in Tanah Bumbu Regency
are heavily influenced by and follow the will of coal
mine businessmen.
Departing from these conclusions, this study
recommends three things. Firstly, the issuance of
coal mining permits should only follow official
procedures in accordance with the provisions of the
regulation. This is not only to strengthen the
institutionalisation of the business licensing system,
but also to avoid unhealthy practices in investment
activity as well as to prevent the occurrence of
environmental damage. Secondly, coal mining
investment activities still have a main commitment
to increase local revenue in order to move the local
economy, to achieve regional progress, and
accelerate the creation of welfare for the people of
the region. Thirdly, the political participation of
businessmen (coal mines) in the political process,
especially the pilkada is certainly permissible and
legitimate, but the assistance provided by the heads
of local chief candidates should be institutionalised
and follow election regulations and the rules of the
General Elections Commission. This is to make the
elections fair, and the elected candidates need not
have a moral and political obligation to mine
businessmen.
REFERENCES
Balmas, Meital, Gideon Rahat, Tamir Sheafer, and Shaul
R. Shenhav. 2014. “Two Routes to Personalized
Politics: Centralized and Decentralized
Personalization.” Party Politics 20(1): 3751.
Boulding, Carew E., and Clark C. Gibson. 2009.
“Supporters or Challengers?: The Effects of
Nongovernmental Organizations on Local Politics
in Bolivia.” Comparative Political Studies 42(4):
479500.
Dinas Pertambangan dan Energi Kalsel. 2011. Resume
Tentang Royalty Dan Perkiraan Alokasi DBH SDA
Pertambangan Umum Tahun Anggaran 2011.
Banjarmasin.
Edlin, Aaron, Andrew Gelman, and Noah Kaplan. 2007.
“Voting as a Rational Choice: Why and How
People Vote to Improve the Well-Being of Others.”
Rationality and Society 19(3): 293314.
Lehtinen, Aki, and Jaakko Kuorikoski. 2007. “Unrealistic
Assumptions in Rational Choice Theory.”
Philosophy of the Social Sciences 37(2): 11538.
Patnaik, Pratyusna. 2013. “Does Political Representation
Ensure Empowerment? Scheduled Tribes in
Decentralised Local Governments of India.”
Journal of South Asian Development 8(1): 2760.
Schotter, Andrew. 2006. “Strong and Wrong: The Use of
Rational Choice Theory in Experimental
Economics.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18(4):
498511.
Sung, Hung En, and Linda Richter. 2007. “Rational
Choice and Environmental Deterrence in the
Retention of Mandated Drug Abuse Treatment
Clients.International Journal of Offender Therapy
and Comparative Criminology 51(6): 686702.
Whitford, Andrew B. 2007. “Decentralized Policy
Implementation.” Political Research Quarterly
60(1): 1730.
ICoCSPA 2018 - International Conference on Contemporary Social and Political Affairs
70