scenario. If the firm does not support a technology, it
is almost impossible for it to use it.
However, due to the introduction of a subsidy, the
structure of Eq. (17) has been changed into the
following:
๐ธ๎ตซ๐ฑ
๎ฏ ,๎ฏง
๎ฏก
๎ตฏ=๐๐ฅ
๎ฏ ,๎ฏง
โ๐
๎ฏก
โ
1
๐๐ฅ
๎ฏ ,๎ฏง
โ๐ถ
๎ฏ ,๎ฏง
๎ฏก
+๐๐ข๐๐ ๐๐๐ฆ>0
(19)
Hence a special case emerges: the condition to
become a switcher can be weaker than the condition
to become a supporter. From Eq. (19), we may
calculate that the critical size of the subsidy is 20.8%.
When ๐๐ข๐๐ ๐๐๐ฆโค20.8%, the condition to become a
switcher is stronger than the condition to become a
supporter. In other words, the prerequisite for
becoming a switcher is to become a supporter. But
when ๐๐ข๐๐ ๐๐๐ฆ>20.8%, the situation will change,
and the prerequisite is no longer necessary. Because
the government subsidies are too strong, many firms
are willing to try to use new technology for
production even if they have not yet become
supporters of it. In such a scenario, many firms try out
the new technology, not because they are optimistic
about the technology, just because they are interested
in the large number of subsidies. Even though these
firms are willing to use niche technology for the
production activities, they do not make any efforts,
such as conducting the experiments or accessing the
supporter network, to develop the new technology.
3.2 Numerical Experiments
Even if the same parameter settings are used, the
model is still affected by random factors. To obtain
meaningful results, we average the outputs of 100
experiments, each of which contains 2600 timesteps
and is under the same initial conditions.
Through these numerical experiments, we found
that when the subsidy rate is higher than 20.8%, both
numbers of supporters and switchers quickly increase
to 100%. But if we cancel the subsidy, the entire
market reverses instantly. Although the number of
supporters can remain above 80%, the number of
switchers instantly becomes single digits, see the top
panel of Fig. 6. This result means that the entire
market is in an abnormally unhealthy state under the
too high subsidy: Firms use the new technology just
for the subsidies; when the subsidy is cancelled, those
firms who are not the real supporters of the new
technology leave the market instantly. Indeed, the
state after the cancellation of subsidy is consistent
with the stable state developed from the beginning
without the subsidy. This means that government
subsidies are completely ineffective. It is a
completely failed policy because the government has
spent huge amounts of money, but they did not reach
the goal of promoting the new technology.
Figure 6: Critical value experiment
(0 - 1500 timesteps: Subsidy = 21%, Spreader = 1.
1500 - 2600 timesteps: Subsidy = 0, Spreader = 1).
4 CONCLUSIONS
Government subsidies are an important factor to help
niche technology grow in the early stage of
technological development. By compensating for the
lack of profitability of technology, it can increase the
expected benefits of firms who have adopted the new
technologies and attract more firms to complete the
technological transition. However, due to regulatory
loopholes and other reasons, companies that only
hope to be decorated with the concept of new
technology or just want to defraud subsidies will
consume many social resources. Moreover, the fake
illusion of prosperity of the new technologies will
present an illusion to the industry and the
government. Once the sign of bubble collapse
emerges, these companies often get out fast causing
chaos in the corresponding industrial field. Therefore,
this article hopes to find the critical condition under
which firms may commit subsidy fraud.
Currently, we have obtained interesting
preliminary results and phenomena. At the same time,
as illustrated in the introduction section, we find that