5 CONCLUSIONS
This study investigates whether presale estimates are
a good predictor of hammer price in the Indian art
market. We use the methodology employed by
Ekelund, Jackson, & Tollison (2013). In their study,
Ekelund, Jackson, & Tollison (2013) argue that
presale estimates consistently underestimate the
hammer price due to both multiplicative and
proportional bias. However, at least in the Indian
market, while multiplicative bias underestimates, the
proportional bias seem to overestimate very
expensive paintings. The joint effect of both the bias
shows that the underestimation happens till the
hammer price is below or equal to US$ 14,357,640;
beyond US$ 14,357,640, the price is overestimated.
This finding is consistent with results of Mei & Moses
(2005), who showed that auction houses
overestimates expensive artworks.
We also find that the characteristics of artwork,
artist, and auction determine the biasedness of
estimates. In agreement with Ashenfelter & Graddy
(2003), our findings also suggest that paintings with
a large area are underestimated. One of the significant
findings of our research is that auction houses do not
follow the same strategy for estimation. Two auction
houses in our study – Saffronart and Pundole's seem
to be more inclined to overestimate, but the rest often
underestimate. In their study, Bauwens & Ginsburgh
(2000) have also noted that the Christie's and
Sotheby's follow different approaches to
under/overestimate.
A systematic underestimation for artists with
higher reputation indicates that buyers are willing to
pay higher than estimates for famous and well-
established artists; however, it is surprising to note
that buyers are more willing to pay higher than
estimates for male artists but not for female artists.
We are curious to know whether the gender-based
differentiation is peculiar to India or prevalent
universally. We have not answered many other
questions in this research, e.g., the biasedness of
estimates in physical vs. online auctions. We hope
future researchers will address these questions.
REFERENCES
Ashenfelter, O. (1989). How auctions work for wine and
art. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 23–36.
Ashenfelter, O., & Graddy, K. (2003). Auctions and the
Price of Art. Journal of Economic Literature,
XLI(September), 763–786.
Baumol, W. (1986). Unnatural Value: Or Art Investment as
Floating Crap Game. American Economic Review,
76(2), 10–14.
Bauwens, L., & Ginsburgh, V. A. (2000). Art experts and
auctions: Are pre-sale estimates unbiased and fully
informative? Louvain Economic Review, 66(2), 131–
144.
Beckert, J., & Rossel, J. (2013). The Price of Art. European
Societies, 15(2), 178–195.
Beggs, A., & Graddy, K. (1997). Declining Values and the
Afternoon Effect : Evidence from Art Auctions. The
RAND Journal of Economics, 28(3), 544–565.
Retrieved from https://www.jstor.org/stable/2556028
Blouin Artinfo. (n.d.).
Brown, R. M. (2009). Art for a Modern India, 1947-1980.
Durham: Duke University Press.
Buelens, N., & Ginsburgh, V. (1993). Revisiting Baumol’s
“art as floating crap game.” European Economic
Review, 37(7), 1351–1371. https://doi.org/10.1016/
0014-2921(93)90060-N
Ekelund, R. B., Jackson, J. D., & Tollison, R. D. (2013).
Are Art Auction Estimates Biased? Southern Economic
Journal, 80(2), 454–465. https://doi.org/10.4284/0038-
4038-2012.087
Ekelund, R. B., Ressler, R. W., & Watson, J. K. (1998).
Estimates, bias and “no sales” in Latin-American art
auctions 1977–1996. Journal of Cultural Economics,
22, 33–42.
Galenson, D. W., & Weinberg, B. A. (2000). Age and
Quality of Work: The Case of Modern American
Painters. Journal of Political Economy, 108(4), 761–
777.
Garay, U. (2020). Determinants of art prices and
performance by movements : Long-run evidence from
an emerging market. Journal of Business Research.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2019.03.057
Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a
Specification Error. Econometrica, 47, 153–161.
Kapur, G. (2000). When Was Modernism: Essays on
Contemporary Cultural Practice in India. New Delhi:
Tulika.
Kennedy, M. (2004). Art market “a cultural obscenity.”
Retrieved April 21, 2022, from https://www.the
guardian.com/uk/2004/jun/03/arts.artsnews
Klamer, A. (2004). Cultural Goods Are Good for More than
Their Economic Value. In V. Rao & M. Walton (Eds.),
Culture and Public Action (pp. 138–162). Stanford:
Stanford University Press.
Kraeussl, R., & van Elsland, N. (2008). Constructing the
True Art Market Index - A Novel 2-Step Hedonic
Approach and its Application to the German Art Market
(CFS Working Paper Series.). Retrieved from
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1104667
McAndrew, C., Smith, J. L., & Thompson, R. (2012). The
Impact of Reserve Prices on the Perceived Bias of
Expert Appraisals of Fine Art. Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 27, 235–252. https://doi.org/10.1002/jae
Mei, J., & Moses, M. (2002). Art as an investment and the
underperformance of masterpieces. American