criteria association influences the entire combination
of criteria, which could be also defined.
Considering a capacity μ on the set N = {1, …,
n}, i.e. a function from 2
N
into IR
+
such as μ(Ø) = 0,
μ(N) = 1, and monotonic (i.e. S, T ⊆ N then μ(S) ≤
μ(T)), the discrete Choquet integral related to the
capacity μ is defined as the function that associates to
any n-uple x = (x
1
, …, x
n
) ∈ IR
n
.
C
μ
(x
1
, …, x
n
) :=
i-1
i=n
(μ(A
σ
(i)
) - μ(A
σ
(i+1))
).x
σ
(i)
(1)
Where σ is a permutation on N such as x
σ
(i)
≤ ….
≤ x
σ
(n)
, and where:
A
σ
(i)
:= {σ(i), …, σ(n)} ∀ i ϵ N, A
σ
(n+1)
= Ø (2)
To simplify notations, we shall write, for any
subset {i
1
, …, i
p
} of N:
μ({i
1
, …, i
p
}) = μ
i1, …, ip
(3)
A particular case of Choquet integral is the simple
weighted sum
i
a
i
.x
i
(
i
a
i
= 1), the values μ(S), S
⊆ N, generalizing here a classical weight vector.
Limit cases of Choquet integral are the Min and Max
operators.
The Choquet integral enables the representation of
non-additive criteria, i.e., with interactions between
pairs or groups of criteria. Its interest consists mainly
in identifying, during a decision-making process,
given a set of values that meet this situation, the better
quality alternative.
2.3 Related Works
The Choquet integral is based on two fundamental
concepts: utility and capacity.
A utility function aims to model the preferences
of the decision maker regarding various possible
input values x
i
. Utility functions can be seen as
making it possible to translate the values of the
attributes x
i
into a satisfaction degree (Kojadinovic,
2009). Utility values are commensurable, monotonic,
and ascending because, if an alternative a is preferred
to b, then u (a) ≥ u (b) (Labreuche, 2009).
A capacity models the fuzzy measure on which
the integral is based and summarizes the importance
of the criteria by aggregating utility functions,
generalizing traditionally used weight vector. The
learning ability of the Choquet integral has been
demonstrated, mainly in (Grabisch, 2008). Functions
dealing with data mining issues such as least square
and linear programming have been used in this
context. Preference learning consists in observing and
learning the preferences of an individual, precisely in
particular when ordering a set of alternatives, to
predict automatic scheduling of a new set of
alternatives (Fürnkranz, 2012).
The Choquet integral learning function is based
on a set of concepts that make it possible to leverage
the consideration of user preferences (or decisions)
and the interaction and/or synergy between the
various criteria for data aggregation. Given a
preferential ordering on a sample learning, the
discrete Choquet integral is able to quantify, then
learn, the relative weights of the different quality
metrics.
In the literature, fuzzy integrals have been used
for different purposes, for preferences or opinions
fusion from a variety of sources, and several
applications and extensions of fuzzy integrals have
been developed. In (Vitor de Campos Souza, 2018),
the authors have proven that the use of fuzzy neural
network is more effective than the decision tree
algorithms often used in the literature. The fuzzy
neural network model allows precision improvement
and less redundancy in decision-making.
In our previous work, we have proven that
applying Choquet integral to order data sources
according to the user's preferences, is an interesting
and challenging area of research and can lead to more
relevant results (Dantan, 2020). One originality of the
work described in this paper consists in the proposal
of an evaluation function attaching to any potential
solution a degree of acceptability, based on truth
degrees of inequality.
3 PROBLEM STATEMENT
Considering a crop with n prediction sources,
information delivered by a source will consists in a
sequence of confidence levels x
i
(d) ∈ [0,1] associated
to future days 1, …, D, given a temporal horizon of D
days. x
i
(d) value reflects the belief of the i
th
source
regarding the occurrence of transition at d day, from
the present phenological stage to the next one. We
have so as many functions d ∈ {1, …, D} → x
i
(d) ∈
[0, 1] as prediction sources i=1, …, n, and x
i
(d) can
be seen as the membership function of a fuzzy subset
of {1, …, D}, 0 meaning a null confidence, and 1 the
maximum value, as presented on figure 2.
No hypothesis can be made here on confidence
levels semantics. In particular, these levels are not
probabilities, only inequalities between two values
issued from the same source being significant. Note
the case with several days having all a 1 value is
possible, reflecting inaccuracy of the prediction.