thus affecting the ongoing Indonesia-Australia
economic cooperation. Firstly, the fact that Australia
is not Indonesia’s favourite trading and investment
partner means that Australia cannot leverage
economic diplomacy to set imperatives for Indonesia
to follow in the free trade regulatory bodies wholly
and completely. He (2008) argued that Indonesia’s
external actions during the Reform era have been
constructed by the mixture of political legitimacy and
international pressure. Yudhoyono and Jokowi had no
problems with their respective political legitimacy
because they were directly elected by the majority
voters in democratic presidential elections. Hence,
the consecutive leaderships which are established are
able to anticipate possible political costs which may
be caused by policies denoting rejections of full scale
liberalisation. In addition, the public in general have
usually supported the government’s protectionist
decisions. Subsequently, AANZFTA and IA-CEPA
only create various processes of mutual
understandings about the need for liberal trade
mechanisms, yet offer little real achievement in
respect to common interests.
Secondly, high tariffs on Australia’s agricultural
exports and non-tariff regulations issued to restrict
Australia’s services can be linked to the politics of
domestic actors, especially the oligarchs, whose
interests have been disadvantaged by the free trade
arrangements in question. In the post-Suharto
unconsolidated democracy, the messages of
protection of people’s interests and the safeguarding
of national sovereignty are easily hijacked by the
oligarchic elites to serve their rent-seeking objectives.
The extension of this political culture to foreign
relations is observable in the state’s behaviour within
regional and bilateral institutions which are
developed with unbalanced contributions in
economic affairs. Drawing on Keohane’s variance of
intergovernmental cooperation and state power
relations (1989), the free trade agreement between
Indonesia and Australia exemplifies the case of low
degree of compliance and high transactional costs.
The reason behind the negotiation is determined by
the dominant political economic players.
Thirdly, the nationalistic features of Jakarta’s
international affairs connect functional and technical
matters with those which are actually the domain of
high politics. Likewise other multilateral
commitments made by Indonesia, which also
encompass Australia, such as ASEAN Regional
Forum (ARF), ASEAN RCEP, and Asia Pacific
Economic Cooperation (APEC), the viability and
feasibility of AANZFTA will be much dependent on
Jakarta’s perception about noneconomic issues, such
as defence and security, in state-to-state interactions.
Laksmana (2017) notices that the 1999 East Timor
crisis and the 2006 Lombok Treaty prove the
importance of Jakarta’s and Canberra’s strategic
assessment on the dynamic developments of wide-
ranging Indonesia-Australia relations. In this context,
the nationalists in Jakarta, both executive and
legislative, still view Australia as an untrusted
partner. Consequently, although not every single
economic initiative from Australia is rebuffed for
historical politico-security reasons, Jakarta always
carefully calculates the impact on national security.
Jakarta prudently witnessed Canberra’s changing
foreign policy approach from favouring Paul
Keating’s multilateralism to adhering to a new type
of bilateralism of preferential trade agreements under
John Howard. This change was not entirely related to
the Howard government’s self-endorsed preference
for relations with Australia’s Asian neighbours, but
the contagious effects of the Asian financial crisis
which was unresolved by the two major regional
institutions of the East Asia, APEC and ASEAN,
which pushed Australia to find a different way to
conduct its immediate external relations.
Washington’s success, which was acquiesced by
Canberra, to promote IMF as opposed to APEC as the
crisis funding helper body for Indonesia, South
Korea, and Thailand at a time American-Australian
links were strengthening alerted Southeast Asians
about the cross-regional powers’ interests outside the
existing economic multilateral institutions. Indonesia
and others crisis affected states fully understood
about Australian regional ambition following the ill
consequences of the IMF’s controlled liberalisation
programs. Howard’s confidence of bilateralism
heightened in the Australian-led INTERFET mission
in East Timor (Lee 2015, 152-53). Jakarta was upset,
and ties with Canberra touched the lowest ebb since
Australia stood by the establishment of Malaysia in
early the 1960s.
Holding distrustful views about Australian
intentions towards its neighbouring Asians, Indonesia
and Malaysia rejected the initiative proposed by the
Howard government to relate ASEAN free trade
(AFTA) and Australia-New Zealand Closer
Economic and Trade Agreement (CER), although
Canberra had contributed to providing economic
rehabilitation assistance in the IMF’s reform
packages. Yet, Australia moved forward with
bilateral free trade talks with other ASEAN countries,
and made good impressions on Singapore and
Thailand, which had initially been appealed to (Lee
2015, 153-54). These evolving events can explain
why Indonesia did not warmly welcome the later