
archy measures the inefficiency of selfish behavior.
It is defined as the ratio of the social welfare un-
der optimum to the Social welfare in equilibrium.
In Gilboa-Freedman, Hassin and Kerner (2014), the
PoA in Naor’s model is shown to have an odd behav-
ior. It increases sharply (from 1.5 to 2) as the arrival
rate comes close to the service rate and becomes un-
bounded exactly when the arrival rate is greater than
the service rate, which is odd since the system is al-
ways stable.
Most relevant to our work is the work of Hassin,
Nowik and Shaki (2018), in which heterogeneity in
service valuation is introduced through a Hotelling-
type model where customers reside in a “linear city”
and incur “transportation costs” from their locations
to the location of the server. Similar models have
been investigated (e.g. D’aspremont & Jaskold,
1979; Dobson & Stavrulaki, 2007; Economides,
1986; Gallay, Olivier and Max-Olivier Hongler, 2008;
Hotelling, 1929; Kwasnica & Euthemia, 2008; Pang-
burn & Stavrulaki, 2008; Ray & Jewkes, 2004; §6.7
and §7.5 in Hassin, 2016) but they all assume a con-
stant density (possibly restricted to an interval). In
contrast, Hassin, Nowik and Shaki allow non-uniform
distributions of customer locations, and the potential
arrival of customers with distances less than x from
the service facility is assumed to be distributed ac-
cording to Poisson with rate λ(x) =
R
x
0
h(y)dy < ∞,
where h(y) is a nonnegative “intensity” function of
the distance y. The definition of λ(x) by an integral is
natural since the customers accumulate from location
0, to location x. The intensity function and (linear)
travel costs jointly generate the distribution of cus-
tomer service valuations. A simple example is a two-
dimensional city, in which the arrival of customers is
uniform. In this case the intensity function can be de-
fined as h(x) = 2πx, and so the arrival of customers
with distances less than x is assumed to be a Poisson
process with rate λ(x) =
R
x
0
2πydy = πx
2
. In a loss
system M/G/1/1, Hassin, Nowik and Shaki (2018) de-
fine the threshold Nash equilibrium strategy x
e
and the
socially-optimal threshold strategy x
∗
. They investi-
gate the dependence of the PoA on the parameter x
e
and the intensity function h. They develop an explicit
formula to calculate lim
x
e
→∞
PoA(h,x
e
) when it exists.
As in Gilboa-Freedman, Hassin and Kerner
(2014), the number 2 arrises repeatadely in several
results of Hassin, Nowik and Shaki (2018), relating
to the limit of PoA when x
e
, goes to infinity. For
instance, if h converges to a positive constant then
PoA converges to 2; if h increases (decreases) then
the limit of PoA is at least (at most) 2. In a system
with a queue they prove that PoA may be unbounded
already in the simplest case of uniform arrival.
The goal of this work is to extend Hassin, Nowik
and Shaki’s model to the case of two servers (instead
of a single server), where server A is located at the
origin and server B is located at a point denoted as
M. If the servers’ points are distsnce from each other
then the system is just a combination of two single-
server systems. It becomes more interesting when the
servers are closer, creating a dilemma for some con-
sumers regarding what service point to arrive at.
The value of information sharing between service
providers lies in its capacity to enhance coordination,
optimize resource allocation, and improve overall sys-
tem efficiency. When service providers have common
knowledge about each other’s status, they can collab-
orate more effectively, leading to a better distribution
of workloads and resources. This coordination of-
ten results in increased efficiency, reduced response
times, and improved service quality. The ability to
access real-time information about the status of other
providers allows for more informed decision-making,
enabling adaptive strategies that respond dynamically
to changing conditions. Ultimately, the value of such
information is reflected in its power to streamline op-
erations, enhance service delivery, and contribute to
a more resilient and responsive system. Think for
example of Air Traffic Control Towers; In a situa-
tion where two air traffic control towers manage ad-
jacent airspaces and are aware of each other’s work-
load, they can coordinate and optimize the allocation
of incoming flights. If one tower is busy, the other
can efficiently handle additional aircraft to maintain
smoother air traffic operations. Another example is
of a hospital with two emergency rooms, if each ER
is aware of the patient load and occupancy status of
the other, medical staff can coordinate patient assign-
ments. Deo and Gurvich (2011) consider a routing
problem motivated by the diversion of ambulances to
neighboring hospitals. These examples illustrate situ-
ations where the level of information sharing between
service providers can significantly impact their abil-
ity to optimize resource allocation and overall system
efficiency.
2 THE M/G/1/1 MODEL:
NOTATIONS AND
FUNDEMENTAL RESULTS
In the model of one server, for all x ≥ 0, customers
with distances less than x, arrive to the system accord-
ing to a Poisson process with rate λ(x) =
x
R
0
h(y)dy,
where h(y) is an intensity function. The service dis-
ICORES 2024 - 13th International Conference on Operations Research and Enterprise Systems
134