unit) will obviously be different from that in a sce-
nario where the manufacturers also compete among
themselves. Thus partition-form based study is es-
sential to capture the frictions in SC.
The first main contribution of this paper is to cap-
ture the above realistic aspects in an SC by model-
ing it as a partition form game and deriving the in-
gredients of the same – to the best of our knowledge,
none of the papers in SC literature consider this. We
further consider that the agents in any coalition op-
erate together as a single unit by pooling the best re-
sources from each partner; furthermore, the possibili-
ties of vertical and/or horizontal cooperation are also
explored.
The exhaustive partition-form game based study
resulted in some interesting insights. When the prod-
uct is essential, and when the customers are (almost)
indifferent to the manufacturers, the grand coalition
is not stable. It is actually the vertical cooperation
between the supplier and one of the manufacturers
that results in a stable configuration. More interest-
ingly, only the collaboration with the stronger manu-
facturer (strong in terms of market power) is stable –
no other attribute of the manufacturers makes a differ-
ence (when their reputation among the customers is
almost the same); the weaker manufacturer operates
alone and competes with the collaborating pair. Even
more interestingly, no collaboration is stable when the
manufacturers are of comparable market strengths.
When the supplier leads by quoting a price, there
exists a Stackelberg equilibrium (SBE) at which the
agents operate, in contrast, a scenario where all the
agents make a simultaneous move results in a Nash
equilibrium at which none of the agents operate. In
fact, majority of the literature in SC seems to under-
stand this at some level and considers the Stackelberg
(SB) framework (e.g., (Li et al., 2023; Zheng et al.,
2021)). The SB framework significantly favours the
supplier – the supplier enjoys a huge fraction of the
revenue generated, which becomes even higher with
the competition at the lower echelon.
The model is described in Section 2, the partition
form games are in Section 4, and the SC is analysed in
Section 5. Some of the proofs are in Appendices, and
others are in technical report (Wadhwa et al., 2024).
Literature Survey. There is a vast literature that
studies the scope of SC coordination. Almost all the
studies consider contract based cooperation (e.g., (Ca-
chon, 2003) and subsequent papers). There are few
strands of literature that study coalition formation
ideas, where the agents are bound without any such
enforcement, because they find it beneficial to do so.
Important and relevant papers in this category are
(Nagarajan and So
ˇ
si
´
c, 2009), (Zheng et al., 2021) and
(Li et al., 2023) etc.
In (Zheng et al., 2021), authors study a two-
echelon sustainable SC with two manufacturers and
a single supplier; they neglect the partition-form as-
pects by defining the worth of a coalition to be the
pessimal worth, the minimum (anticipated worth) that
the said coalition can generate irrespective of the ar-
rangement of the left-over agents. However, if a coali-
tion (not currently operating) has to block/oppose an
operating configuration (the set of operating coali-
tions and revenues/shares of all the agents of SC),
the coalition should anticipate to derive a better rev-
enue than the sum total revenue that its members
are currently deriving. In other words, the anticipa-
tion is required only for estimating the worth of fu-
ture (or blocking) coalition (as upfront it is not sure
of the retaliatory actions of the others), and not for
the worth currently derived (as considered in (Zheng
et al., 2021)). We consider pessimal worth as the an-
ticipated worth of blocking-coalition, while the (cur-
rent) worth(s) in any operating configuration is de-
rived by solving an appropriate game or optimization
problem.
Another recent study in (Li et al., 2023) consid-
ers two assemblers (like manufacturers in our study)
and many irreplaceable suppliers, where the second
assembler only competes for customer base and has
its own set of suppliers – hence this study is not di-
rectly comparable to ours. However, the study again
neglects the partition form nature of the game – the
worth of any coalition is defined just based on its size.
As already argued, when one neglects the inherent
partition form nature, the results could be misleading
– it would be interesting to analyze the SC of (Li et al.,
2023), after incorporating partition form aspects.
In (Nagarajan and So
ˇ
si
´
c, 2009), authors study
coalitional stability considering partition-form as-
pects. However, as is mentioned in the same paper,
they do not consider the worth of the coalition (based
on partition), rather assume that all the players in the
coalition to agree to quote a common (best) price.
This (rather restricted) assumption facilitates in the
derivation of the revenue generated by a single agent
in any partition and thereby study the stability aspects.
In our study, we derive the utility of any coalition de-
pending upon the partition and then consider stability
aspects based on the division of that worth and the
anticipated utility of the ‘opposing coalition’.
2 MODEL
We consider a two-echelon supply chain (SC), with
two manufacturers at the lower echelon and a single
Partition-Form Cooperative Games in Two-Echelon Supply Chains
159