
preferred college of s. Therefore, the best-case condi-
tion holds regardless of what the RHS is.
We now show that the worst-case condition holds
for every s ∈ S in the categories (i) and (ii). For (i)
students s ̸∈ r
o
, when the parent of s does not invite s,
s is unmatched. Since IBSI-TTC never matches any
student to a college that she is not willing to go, this
is a worst-case, regardless of what s reports. Thus,
both LHS and RHS of the worst-case condition is ∅,
implying that the worst-case condition holds.
For (ii) students s ∈ r
o
who have at least one child,
let θ
s
:= (≻
s
, r
s
) be the true preference of s. Phase 1
of IBSI-TTC is resistant to preference misreport, from
the known property of TTC in the traditional setting.
Thus, when s arbitrarily misreports her preference, τ
1
gets weakly worse. Also, the tentative outcome at
Phase 1 is identical, regardless to s’s invitation strat-
egy r
′
s
. Let τ
′
1
be the tentative outcome at Phase 1 un-
der s’s arbitrary misreport θ
′
s
. We then have τ
1
≿
s
τ
′
1
.
Furthermore, there is a possible profile of reports
θ
′
−s
∈ R(θ
−s
) by the other students so that students
in distance larger than one prefer to be unmatched.
Under such a profile, the final outcome coincides with
the Phase 1 outcome. That is, τ
1
is an upper bound of
the worst-case outcome, even from the viewpoint of
true preference ≻
s
of s, implying both
τ
1
≿
s
W
≻
s
(θ
s
) and τ
′
1
≿
s
W
≻
s
(θ
′
s
).
Also, Lemma 10 implies W
≻
s
(θ
s
) ≿
s
τ
1
. Thus,
W
≻
s
(θ
s
) ∼
s
τ
1
≿
s
τ
′
1
≿
s
W
≻
s
(θ
′
s
) holds, which guaran-
tees that the worst-case condition of NOM holds.
IBSI-TTC violates FR, FRN, WNW, MB, and
MB-D. This is mainly due to two facts. First, it is
based on TTC, which violates FRN (and thus FR).
Second, it ignores direct children of o if they do not
invite any students, which is totally wasteful and re-
sults in an unstable outcome. However, we believe
that the idea behind the IBSI-TTC mechanism, guar-
anteeing NOM only and not paying too much atten-
tion to achieve SP, will be a useful building block for
designing better NOM mechanisms in the future.
7 CONCLUDING REMARKS
Our model of two-sided matching with strategic invi-
tation is limited in the sense that the social network
among students are restricted as a tree-shaped. Han-
dling more general structures would be a promising
future direction. For each impossibility theorem, it
would also be required to show the independence of
the properties by providing mechanisms satisfying all
except one properties, though we strongly believe that
they are independent. Diffusion mechanism design
is still a new and developing model of mechanism
design. We believe there are further various exten-
sions to achieve relatively positive results, including
restricting preferences and allowing randomization.
REFERENCES
Abdulkadiro
˘
glu, A. and S
¨
onmez, T. (2003). School choice:
A mechanism design approach. American Economic Re-
view, 93(3):729–747.
Ando, R., Kimura, K., Todo, T., and Yokoo, M. (2025).
Parameterized voter relevance in facility location games
with tree-shaped invitation graphs. To appear in Proc.
WALCOM ’25.
Aziz, H., Baychkov, A., and Bir
´
o, P. (2020). Summer in-
ternship matching with funding constraints. In Proc. AA-
MAS ’20, pages 97–104.
Cho, S.-H., Todo, T., and Yokoo, M. (2022). Two-sided
matching over social networks. In Proc. IJCAI-ECAI ’22,
pages 186–193.
Crawford, V. P. (1991). Comparative statics in matching
markets. J. Econ. Theory, 54(2):389–400.
Gale, D. and Shapley, L. S. (1962). College admissions and
the stability of marriage. The American Mathematical
Monthly, 69(1):9–15.
Hall, P. (1935). On representatives of subsets. J. the London
Mathematical Society, s1-10(1):26–30.
Kawasaki, T., Barrot, N., Takanashi, S., Todo, T., and
Yokoo, M. (2020). Strategy-proof and non-wasteful
multi-unit auction via social network. In Proc. AAAI ’20,
pages 2062–2069.
Kawasaki, T., Wada, R., Todo, T., and Yokoo, M. (2021).
Mechanism design for housing markets over social net-
works. In Proc. AAMAS ’21, pages 692–700.
Kurata, R., Hamada, N., Iwasaki, A., and Yokoo, M. (2017).
Controlled school choice with soft bounds and overlap-
ping types. J. Artif. Intell. Res., 58:153–184.
Li, B., Hao, D., Zhao, D., and Zhou, T. (2017). Mechanism
design in social networks. In Proc. AAAI ’17, pages 586–
592.
Li, M., Cao, Y., and Zhao, D. (2024). Double auction on
diffusion network. In Proc. AAAI ’24, pages 9848–9855.
Ortega, J. and Klein, T. (2023). The cost of strategy-
proofness in school choice. Games and Economic Be-
havior, 141:515–528.
Rastegari, B., Condon, A., Immorlica, N., and Leyton-
Brown, K. (2013). Two-sided matching with partial in-
formation. In Proc. ACM-EC ’13, pages 733–750.
Todo, T., Wada, R., Yahiro, K., and Yokoo, M. (2021). Lazy
gale-shapley for many-to-one matching with partial in-
formation. In Proc. ADT ’21, pages 390–405.
Troyan, P. and Morrill, T. (2020). Obvious manipulations.
J. Econ. Theory, 185:104970.
You, B., Dierks, L., Todo, T., Li, M., and Yokoo, M.
(2022). Strategy-proof house allocation with existing
tenants over social networks. In Proc. AAMAS ’22, pages
1446–1454.
Strategy-Proofness and Non-Obvious Manipulability of Top-Trading-Cycles with Strategic Invitations
623